Return to Video

Applications Using Elasticity

  • 0:00 - 0:03
    ♪ (music) ♪
  • 0:09 - 0:10
    [Alex] In the last video,
  • 0:10 - 0:13
    Tyler introduced
    the topic of slave redemption
  • 0:13 - 0:17
    and how elasticity can help us
    to understand its consequences.
  • 0:17 - 0:20
    In this video,
    we'll dive deeper into this problem
  • 0:20 - 0:24
    and show how to analyze it using
    supply, demand, and elasticity.
  • 0:24 - 0:26
    We'll also look
  • 0:26 - 0:28
    at some other real world
    applications of elasticity.
  • 0:28 - 0:29
    Let's get started.
  • 0:34 - 0:36
    [Tyler] Okay, let's begin our analysis.
  • 0:36 - 0:38
    We'll put the price of slaves
    on the vertical axis,
  • 0:38 - 0:40
    the quantity on the horizontal axis.
  • 0:40 - 0:45
    And this is the demand for slaves
    from potential slave owners.
  • 0:45 - 0:48
    So, this is the demand --
    if you like -- from the bad guys.
  • 0:48 - 0:51
    It often helps in these situations
    to begin with a polar case.
  • 0:51 - 0:54
    So let's assume to start
    with that the supply of slaves
  • 0:54 - 0:58
    is perfectly inelastic --
    that is, it doesn't respond at all --
  • 0:58 - 1:02
    quantity supplied of slaves
    does not respond to the price.
  • 1:02 - 1:06
    Given these assumptions,
    the equilibrium is found at point A
  • 1:06 - 1:09
    with a price of slaves
    of $15 per slave
  • 1:09 - 1:12
    and with 1,000 people being enslaved --
  • 1:12 - 1:14
    being put into captivity
  • 1:14 - 1:16
    every period --
    every year, in this case.
  • 1:16 - 1:17
    Now...
  • 1:18 - 1:20
    what does the redemption program do?
  • 1:21 - 1:24
    Well, what the redemption
    program does is it increases
  • 1:24 - 1:25
    the demand for slaves.
  • 1:26 - 1:27
    So the demand for slaves
  • 1:27 - 1:31
    now shifts out --
    twists out -- to this red curve.
  • 1:31 - 1:35
    And this is the demand
    from the potential slave owners
  • 1:35 - 1:37
    plus the demand from the redeemers.
  • 1:37 - 1:40
    So, this is the total
    demand for slaves.
  • 1:40 - 1:43
    And with that new
    increased total demand,
  • 1:43 - 1:46
    what we see
    is the equilibrium is at point B
  • 1:47 - 1:51
    with a price of slaves
    of $50 per slave.
  • 1:51 - 1:57
    Now -- that increased price
    of slaves is a good thing
  • 1:57 - 1:58
    from the point of view
    of the program
  • 1:58 - 2:01
    because it's precisely
    that higher price
  • 2:01 - 2:04
    which is going to discourage
    the potential slave owners
  • 2:04 - 2:07
    from buying slaves.
  • 2:07 - 2:11
    It's that higher price
    which prices them out of the market.
  • 2:11 - 2:12
    What the redeemers
    are really doing is they're making
  • 2:12 - 2:15
    slaves too expensive
    for potential slave owners to buy.
  • 2:18 - 2:19
    So the potential slave owners
  • 2:19 - 2:23
    start off at a price of $15
    buying 1,000 slaves.
  • 2:23 - 2:26
    At the higher price of $50,
  • 2:26 - 2:31
    the potential slave owners
    only buy 200 slaves.
  • 2:31 - 2:33
    So, 200 slaves end up
    being held in captivity
  • 2:33 - 2:36
    after the redemption
    program -- per year --
  • 2:36 - 2:40
    compared to 1,000
    before the redemption program.
  • 2:41 - 2:43
    So, what the redemption program does
  • 2:43 - 2:46
    is it ends up freeing 800 slaves.
  • 2:46 - 2:48
    And in this situation
  • 2:48 - 2:51
    where the supply curve
    is perfectly inelastic,
  • 2:51 - 2:53
    the program works quite well --
  • 2:53 - 2:58
    in the sense that every freed slave
  • 2:59 - 3:01
    would have been a slave
  • 3:01 - 3:06
    had it not been
    for the redemption program.
  • 3:06 - 3:09
    That is --
    of these 800 freed slaves --
  • 3:09 - 3:10
    all of them
    would have been held in captivity
  • 3:10 - 3:12
    were it not
    for the redemption program.
  • 3:12 - 3:16
    And what we're going
    to see in a minute,
  • 3:16 - 3:21
    is that when the supply curve
    is more elastic, that's not the case.
  • 3:21 - 3:24
    When the supply curve is more elastic,
  • 3:24 - 3:27
    the redemption program itself
    can increase the number of people
  • 3:27 - 3:32
    who are enslaved
    at least for a period of time.
  • 3:32 - 3:33
    So let's take a look
    now at the case
  • 3:33 - 3:35
    where the supply curve
    is more elastic.
  • 3:35 - 3:36
    So now, we're basically
    going to repeat the analysis
  • 3:36 - 3:38
    but with a more elastic supply curve.
  • 3:38 - 3:41
    So here's our demand curve --
    just the same as we had it before.
  • 3:41 - 3:43
    Here's our more
    elastic supply curve.
  • 3:43 - 3:44
    Notice that I've drawn the curves
  • 3:44 - 3:46
    so that the equilibrium is exactly
    the same as it was before --
  • 3:46 - 3:48
    that is, at point A.
  • 3:50 - 3:51
    The price of slaves
    is $15 per slave
  • 3:51 - 3:54
    and there are 1,000 people
  • 3:54 - 3:57
    who are enslaved
    in our initial equilibrium --
  • 3:57 - 4:01
    again -- exactly as we had before.
  • 4:01 - 4:04
    Now what does
    the redemption program do?
  • 4:05 - 4:10
    It increases the demand for slaves.
  • 4:10 - 4:12
    At the new higher demand --
    okay, we’re at point B --
  • 4:12 - 4:15
    is our new equilibrium.
  • 4:15 - 4:16
    At point B,
  • 4:16 - 4:18
    notice that the price
    of slaves is $30 per slave.
  • 4:18 - 4:19
    Not $50 per slave --
  • 4:19 - 4:21
    the price has not gone
    up as much as it did before.
  • 4:21 - 4:24
    Why not?
  • 4:24 - 4:26
    Well, the price hasn't gone
    up as much as it did before
  • 4:26 - 4:29
    because now the higher price
    induces a greater quantity supplied.
  • 4:29 - 4:36
    So now, what the redeemers
    have done by increasing
  • 4:36 - 4:39
    the demand for slaves,
  • 4:39 - 4:40
    they've increased the incentive
  • 4:40 - 4:42
    of the slave traders to go
    out and capture more slaves.
  • 4:42 - 4:45
    And indeed, before,
  • 4:45 - 4:48
    the slave traders were capturing
    1,000 people per period --
  • 4:48 - 4:54
    now they're capturing
    2,200 people per period.
  • 4:54 - 4:58
    So there's been
    an increase of people
  • 4:59 - 5:02
    who are enslaved --
    who are put into slavery -- of 1,200.
  • 5:05 - 5:08
    The program still works
    in the following sense.
  • 5:08 - 5:10
    The quantity of slaves
  • 5:10 - 5:13
    demanded by the potential
    slave owners does fall,
  • 5:13 - 5:19
    not as much as before
  • 5:21 - 5:22
    because the price
    isn't driven up as high.
  • 5:22 - 5:23
    But the price rises from $15 to $30
  • 5:23 - 5:24
    and that reduces
    the quantity of slaves
  • 5:24 - 5:25
    demanded by the potential
    slave owners to 600.
  • 5:25 - 5:29
    So the program
    is still successful
  • 5:29 - 5:32
    in the sense
    that before the program begins,
  • 5:32 - 5:35
    1,000 people are held in captivity.
  • 5:35 - 5:36
    After the program,
    only 600 people are held in captivity,
  • 5:36 - 5:38
    so 400 people are freed.
  • 5:38 - 5:46
    However, those 400 net freed
  • 5:48 - 5:51
    come at a high price
  • 5:52 - 5:53
    because now 1,200 additional people
  • 5:53 - 5:55
    are put into slavery --
    at least, for some period of time.
  • 5:55 - 6:02
    A bunch of them
    are then bought up
  • 6:02 - 6:04
    but 1,200 of the 1,600 people
  • 6:04 - 6:05
    who are redeemed
    would not have been slaves
  • 6:05 - 6:07
    had it not been
    for the redemption program.
  • 6:07 - 6:08
    So the redemption program ends up
  • 6:08 - 6:09
    in a sense, freeing more people --
  • 6:09 - 6:11
    the number of people
    freed on the books is 1,600.
  • 6:11 - 6:17
    But 1,200 of those
    wouldn't have been slaves
  • 6:23 - 6:26
    had it not been
    for the redemption program itself
  • 6:29 - 6:30
    driving up the price of slaves
  • 6:30 - 6:32
    and the incentive
    to capture more slaves.
  • 6:32 - 6:39
    So, on net, only 400 people
    are actually freed.
  • 6:39 - 6:43
    So the program is less successful
  • 6:43 - 6:44
    when the supply curve
    is more elastic,
  • 6:44 - 6:46
    really, for two reasons.
  • 6:46 - 6:49
    First, the number of people
    who are freed on net goes down --
  • 6:49 - 6:52
    we don't get as big a drop
    in the quantity of slaves demanded
  • 6:52 - 6:57
    because the price
    doesn't go up as much.
  • 6:57 - 6:58
    The second reason, however,
  • 6:58 - 7:00
    is that in order
    to get that net freed,
  • 7:00 - 7:03
    we've actually created more slaves,
  • 7:03 - 7:08
    we've actually created
    more people who are captured.
  • 7:08 - 7:14
    So at the end of the day,
    400 people are still freed.
  • 7:15 - 7:18
    On net, fewer people end up
    being slaves at the end of the day,
  • 7:18 - 7:19
    but to get there
    at the beginning of the day,
  • 7:19 - 7:22
    we've got a lot more
    people who are enslaved --
  • 7:22 - 7:25
    who were taken
    by the slave traders.
  • 7:25 - 7:28
    So this makes it very difficult.
  • 7:28 - 7:30
    The more elastic
    the supply curve is,
  • 7:30 - 7:33
    the less successful
    the program can be
  • 7:33 - 7:38
    and the more of these terrible,
    terrible trade- offs that there are.
  • 7:38 - 7:40
    And if we remember some of the facts
  • 7:40 - 7:41
    about elasticity in particular,
  • 7:41 - 7:43
    remember supply curves
    get more elastic in the long run --
  • 7:43 - 7:48
    well that's exactly what we saw
    in the case in the Sudan.
  • 7:48 - 7:54
    At the beginning,
  • 7:55 - 7:58
    the redemption program
    increased the price of slaves a lot,
  • 7:58 - 7:59
    but as the supply curve
    became more elastic over time,
  • 7:59 - 8:01
    the price of slaves
    began to fall back down again.
  • 8:01 - 8:05
    It was not increased by as much.
  • 8:05 - 8:12
    And thus, this redemption program
    became less successful over time.
  • 8:13 - 8:15
    So, this is a very tricky issue.
  • 8:15 - 8:18
    It's a very controversial issue.
  • 8:18 - 8:19
    Did the groups like Christian
    Solidarity International --
  • 8:19 - 8:22
    were they on net helpful?
  • 8:22 - 8:24
    There are these terrible trade-offs.
  • 8:24 - 8:25
    Economics can't answer this question,
  • 8:25 - 8:29
    but it can at least point
    to the supply response
  • 8:29 - 8:32
    and what that means in moral terms.
  • 8:32 - 8:35
    Let's look at another application.
  • 8:35 - 8:37
    Let's look at another
    important question
  • 8:37 - 8:40
    which we can analyze
    using demand and supply.
  • 8:40 - 8:44
    What is the effect of gun buybacks?
  • 8:44 - 8:46
    Now these buybacks are often
    sponsored by local governments,
  • 8:46 - 8:49
    the local police,
    the local mayor and so forth.
  • 8:49 - 8:55
    In this buyback --
    which was held in Oakland --
  • 8:55 - 8:57
    the officials offered $250 cash
  • 8:57 - 9:00
    for each working gun,
    no questions asked.
  • 9:00 - 9:05
    They then collected the guns
    and they melted them down.
  • 9:05 - 9:07
    The idea was to get
    guns off the street.
  • 9:07 - 9:08
    They ended up collecting
    about 500 guns in this buyback.
  • 9:08 - 9:10
    These buybacks are often held.
  • 9:10 - 9:11
    There's been one
    in Washington, D.C.
  • 9:11 - 9:14
    and Rochester, New York,
    and throughout the United States.
  • 9:14 - 9:19
    They're fairly common
    again at the local level.
  • 9:19 - 9:24
    The question is:
    can these buybacks be effective?
  • 9:24 - 9:26
    And to answer that we need
    to make some assumptions
  • 9:26 - 9:29
    or we need to know something
    about demand and supply.
  • 9:29 - 9:33
    In particular,
    what assumptions would make sense
  • 9:33 - 9:36
    about the elasticity of supply?
  • 9:36 - 9:38
    Is the supply curve of guns
    to a city like Washington, D.C.
  • 9:38 - 9:39
    or Oakland, California --
  • 9:39 - 9:41
    is that supply curve going
    to be inelastic or elastic?
  • 9:41 - 9:49
    Bear in mind what that means.
  • 9:49 - 9:54
    So we're looking at the elasticity
    of supply of guns in a city
  • 9:54 - 9:57
    like Washington, D.C. or a town.
  • 9:57 - 10:02
    Also bear in mind
    that in the United States
  • 10:04 - 10:05
    as a whole -- there are
    hundreds of millions of guns --
  • 10:05 - 10:06
    and that guns continue
    to be produced, manufactured,
  • 10:06 - 10:08
    bought and sold every day.
  • 10:08 - 10:11
    So what assumptions
  • 10:11 - 10:12
    would you make
    about the local supply curve
  • 10:12 - 10:14
    of guns in a city
    like Washington, D.C.?
  • 10:14 - 10:18
    Think about that.
  • 10:18 - 10:21
    I'll give you an answer
    on the next slide.
  • 10:21 - 10:27
    The supply of guns to a local
    region is going to be very elastic.
  • 10:27 - 10:34
    Remember our earlier example
    of suppose that we have an increase
  • 10:35 - 10:36
    in demand for gasoline
    in Washington, D.C. --
  • 10:36 - 10:39
    is that going to increase the price
    of gasoline in Washington, D.C.?
  • 10:39 - 10:43
    The answer is no,
  • 10:43 - 10:44
    because just a tiny
    increase in price
  • 10:44 - 10:46
    and lots of gasoline
    will come in from Virginia,
  • 10:46 - 10:48
    from Maryland,
    from other states in the country.
  • 10:50 - 10:57
    Remember, the more local the supply,
    the more elastic the supply curve.
  • 10:57 - 11:02
    So an increase in the demand for gasoline
    in Washington, D.C. -- that's not going to increase the world price of gasoline.
  • 11:02 - 11:07
    And it's not even going to increase the price of gasoline in Washington, D.C., because if it did people would start to sell gas in Washington, D.C. instead of next door, in Virginia or Maryland.
  • 11:17 - 11:21
    So the price has got to be about the same throughout the
    United States.
  • 11:21 - 11:24
    The same thing is true for guns.
  • 11:24 - 11:27
    The supply of guns to a local region
    like Oakland or Washington, D.C. is going to be very elastic.
  • 11:27 - 11:31
    That has surprising facts.
  • 11:31 - 11:34
    It means that local buybacks won't
  • 11:34 - 11:39
    affect the number of guns on the street
    nor even their price. Let's take a look at
  • 11:40 - 11:48
    the diagram. Here is our demand curve for
    guns. Here's our supply curve, which is
  • 11:48 - 11:53
    drawn very elastic because it's a local
    market. The initial equilibrium is at
  • 11:53 - 11:57
    point A at a certain price of guns and a
    certain quantity of guns traded each
  • 11:57 - 12:00
    period. What the buyback does is
  • 12:00 - 12:04
    it increases the demand for guns,
    shifting the equilibrium
  • 12:04 - 12:08
    to point B.
    So the buyback, they end up buying a lot of
  • 12:08 - 12:13
    guns, but all of the guns they end up
    buying come from the increase in the
  • 12:14 - 12:20
    quantity supplied. Notice that the buyback
    doesn't push the price of guns up. Because
  • 12:20 - 12:25
    it doesn't push the price of guns up, no
    one stops buying a gun. Remember, a
  • 12:25 - 12:32
    buyback is going to be effective only if
    it makes guns more expensive, only if it
  • 12:32 - 12:34
    reduces the quantity demanded of guns.
  • 12:34 - 12:39
    Since all of the increase in supply
    is being generated by
  • 12:39 - 12:43
    the buyback itself, the buyback doesn't
    increase the price of guns in Washington,
  • 12:43 - 12:47
    D.C., therefore it doesn't reduce the
    quantity demanded of guns in Washington,
  • 12:47 - 12:53
    D.C., therefore no effect on the number of
    guns held. Now in particular what's going
  • 12:53 - 12:59
    to happen is that if the mayor offers $250
    for a gun, people are going to go into
  • 13:00 - 13:03
    their closet, they're going to find an old
    low-quality gun, a gun they don't really
  • 13:03 - 13:08
    want. They're going to turn that in and
    maybe a few weeks or a few months later,
  • 13:08 - 13:13
    they're going to buy a new gun. Think
    about it this way. Imagine for whatever
  • 13:13 - 13:18
    odd reason that the government in
    Washington, D.C. wanted to reduce the
  • 13:18 - 13:25
    number of people wearing sneakers so they
    offered a sneaker buyback. For $50 they
  • 13:25 - 13:31
    would buy any pair of sneakers - no
    questions asked. Well, of course people
  • 13:31 - 13:34
    are going to go into their closet, they're
    going to find old pairs of sneakers they
  • 13:34 - 13:37
    don't really want anymore and they're
    going to turn those in. They're going to
  • 13:37 - 13:42
    sell, they're going to sell those sneakers
    to the government. But is anyone in
  • 13:43 - 13:48
    Washington, D.C. going to end up in the
    long run going shoeless, even going
  • 13:48 - 13:53
    sneaker-less? No. They may turn their
    sneakers in, but a few weeks, a few months
  • 13:53 - 13:57
    later they're going to be buying a new
    pair of sneakers. We haven't changed the
  • 13:57 - 14:01
    price of sneakers, therefore we haven't
    changed the quantity demanded of sneakers,
  • 14:02 - 14:05
    therefore we're going to stay at the
    equilibrium.
  • 14:05 - 14:11
    Once the buyback is over, we're going to be
    at the same equilibrium at point A. So
  • 14:11 - 14:18
    local gun buybacks don't work. They're
    really in my view a waste of time. This
  • 14:19 - 14:22
    doesn't mean that we can't do anything. We
    may want to put more police on the street,
  • 14:23 - 14:27
    we may want to fight crime in other ways,
    but a local gun buyback isn't going to
  • 14:27 - 14:34
    work. Another point, a few countries, such
    as Australia, that had required buybacks,
  • 14:34 - 14:39
    mandatory buybacks, where they ban guns and
    then buy them back. Well, since that's, A
  • 14:39 - 14:44
    Mandatory, and B for the country as a
    whole, that might get guns off the street,
  • 14:44 - 14:51
    but here we're talking about a local
    buyback. And because of the elasticity of
  • 14:52 - 14:56
    supply, it's not going to affect the number
    of guns on the local streets nor even
  • 14:57 - 15:03
    their price and thus it's going to be, in
    my view, completely ineffective. It's
  • 15:03 - 15:08
    really quite amazing how a little bit of
    economics can go a long way to
  • 15:08 - 15:14
    understanding and improving public policy.
    Hopefully you see the argument about the
  • 15:15 - 15:19
    elasticity of supply of guns and yet we
    see these policies being passed all the
  • 15:19 - 15:24
    time, these ineffective policies are
    actually often put into place. A little
  • 15:24 - 15:28
    bit of economics goes a long way to
    improving public policy, if only we can
  • 15:28 - 15:34
    get the message out. Okay, thanks very
    much. See you, uh, next chapter.
  • 15:36 - 15:41
    - [Announcer] If you want to test yourself,
    click “Practice Questions.” Or, if you're
  • 15:41 - 15:44
    ready to move on, just click “Next Video.”
  • 15:44 - 15:46
    ♪ (music) ♪
Title:
Applications Using Elasticity
Description:

In this video, we take a look at real-world applications of elasticity, using the examples of slave redemption in Sudan and and the effects of gun buyback programs in the U.S.

Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/elasticity-examples-applications#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/taxes-subsidies-definition-tax-wedge

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
15:49

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions