Return to Video

Applications Using Elasticity

  • 0:02 - 0:04
    ♪ (music) ♪
  • 0:09 - 0:13
    [Alex] In the last video,
    Tyler introduced
    the topic of slave redemption
  • 0:13 - 0:18
    and how elasticity can help us
    to understand its consequences.
  • 0:18 - 0:23
    In this video, we'll dive deeper
    into this problem and show
    how to analyze it using supply,
    demand, and elasticity.
  • 0:23 - 0:28
    We'll also look at some other
    real world applications of elasticity.
  • 0:28 - 0:30
    Let's get started.
  • 0:34 - 0:37
    Okay, let's begin our analysis.
    We'll put the price of slaves on the
  • 0:37 - 0:42
    vertical axis, the quantity on the
    horizontal axis. And this is the demand
  • 0:42 - 0:47
    for slaves from potential slave owners. So
    this is the demand, if you like, from the
  • 0:47 - 0:51
    bad guys. It often helps in these
    situations to begin with a polar case.
  • 0:51 - 0:56
    So let's assume to start with that the
    supply of slaves is perfectly inelastic.
  • 0:56 - 0:58
    That is it doesn't respond at all.
  • 0:58 - 1:02
    Quantity supplied of slaves does not
    respond to the price.
  • 1:03 - 1:08
    Given these assumptions the equilibrium is
    found at point A with a price of slaves of
  • 1:08 - 1:13
    $15 per slave and with 1,000 people
    being enslaved, being put into captivity
  • 1:14 - 1:21
    every period, every year, in this case. Now
    what does the redemption program do? Well,
  • 1:21 - 1:26
    what the redemption program does is it
    increases the demand for slaves. So the
  • 1:26 - 1:32
    demand for slaves now shifts out, twists
    out, to this red curve and this is the
  • 1:32 - 1:37
    demand from the potential slave owners
    plus the demand from the redeemers. So
  • 1:38 - 1:43
    this is the total demand for slaves. And
    with that new increased total demand, what
  • 1:43 - 1:52
    we see is the equilibrium is at point B
    with a price of slaves of $50 per slave.
  • 1:52 - 1:57
    Now, that increased price of slaves is a
    good thing from the point of view of the
  • 1:57 - 2:04
    program because it's precisely that higher
    price which is going to discourage the
  • 2:04 - 2:10
    potential slave owners from buying slaves.
    It's that higher price which prices them
  • 2:10 - 2:14
    out of the market. What the redeemers are
    really doing is they're making slaves too
  • 2:14 - 2:20
    expensive for potential slave owners to
    buy. So the potential slave owners start
  • 2:20 - 2:26
    off at a price of $15 buying 1,000
    slaves. At the higher price of $50, the
  • 2:26 - 2:33
    potential slave owners only buy 200
    slaves. So 200 slaves end up being held in
  • 2:33 - 2:39
    captivity after the redemption program per
    year compared to 1,000 before the
  • 2:39 - 2:45
    redemption program. So what the redemption
    program does is it ends up freeing 800
  • 2:45 - 2:51
    slaves. And in this situation where the
    supply curve is perfectly inelastic, the
  • 2:51 - 3:01
    program works quite well in the sense that
    every freed slave would have been a slave
  • 3:01 - 3:06
    had it not been for the redemption
    program. That is, of these 800 freed
  • 3:06 - 3:12
    slaves, all of them would have been held
    in captivity were it not for the
  • 3:12 - 3:16
    redemption program. And what we're going
    to see in a minute is that when the supply
  • 3:16 - 3:21
    curve is more elastic, that's not the
    case. When the supply curve is more
  • 3:21 - 3:26
    elastic, the redemption program itself can
    increase the number of people who are
  • 3:27 - 3:32
    enslaved at least for a period of time. So
    let's take a look now at the case where
  • 3:32 - 3:36
    the supply curve is more elastic. So now
    we're basically going to repeat the
  • 3:36 - 3:41
    analysis but with a more elastic supply
    curve. So here's our demand curve just the
  • 3:41 - 3:45
    same as we had it before. Here's our more
    elastic supply curve. Notice that I've
  • 3:46 - 3:50
    drawn the curves so that the equilibrium
    is exactly the same as it was before, that
  • 3:50 - 3:57
    is at point A. The price of slaves is $15
    per slave and there are 1,000 people
  • 3:57 - 4:01
    who are enslaved in our initial
    equilibrium, again exactly as we had
  • 4:01 - 4:04
    before.
    Now what does the redemption program do?
  • 4:05 - 4:10
    It increases the demand for slaves. At the
    new higher demand, ok we’re at point B, is
  • 4:10 - 4:18
    our new equilibrium. At point B, notice
    that the price of slaves is $30 per slave.
  • 4:18 - 4:24
    Not $50 per slave - the price has not gone
    up as much as it did before. Why not?
  • 4:24 - 4:29
    Well, the price hasn't gone up as much as
    it did before because now the higher price
  • 4:29 - 4:36
    induces a greater quantity supplied. So
    now what the redeemers have done by
  • 4:36 - 4:42
    increasing the demand for slaves, they've
    increased the incentive of the slave
  • 4:42 - 4:48
    traders to go out and capture more slaves.
    And indeed before the slave traders were
  • 4:48 - 4:54
    capturing 1,000 people per period,
    now they're capturing 2,200 people per
  • 4:54 - 4:58
    period. So there's been an increase of
    people who are enslaved, who are put into
  • 4:58 - 5:08
    slavery of 1,200. The program still works
    in the following sense. The quantity of
  • 5:08 - 5:13
    slaves demanded by the potential slave
    owners does fall, not as much as before
  • 5:13 - 5:19
    because the price isn't driven up as high,
    but the price rises from $15 to $30 and
  • 5:19 - 5:25
    that reduces the quantity of slaves
    demanded by the potential slave owners to
  • 5:25 - 5:32
    600. So the program is still successful in
    the sense that before the program begins
  • 5:32 - 5:38
    1,000 people are held in captivity.
    After the program, only 600 people are
  • 5:38 - 5:46
    held in captivity, so 400 people are freed.
    However, those 400 net freed come at a
  • 5:46 - 5:55
    high price because now 1,200 additional
    people are put into slavery, at least for
  • 5:55 - 6:02
    some period of time. A bunch of them are
    then bought up but 1,200 of the 1,600
  • 6:02 - 6:07
    people who are redeemed would not have
    been slaves had it not been for the
  • 6:07 - 6:10
    redemption program.
    So the redemption program ends up in a
  • 6:11 - 6:17
    sense freeing more people - the number of
    people freed on the books is 1,600. But
  • 6:17 - 6:26
    1,200 of those wouldn't have been slaves
    had it not been for the redemption program
  • 6:26 - 6:31
    itself driving up the price of slaves and
    the incentive to capture more slaves. So
  • 6:32 - 6:39
    on net, only 400 people are actually
    freed. So the program is less successful
  • 6:39 - 6:46
    when the supply curve is more elastic
    really for two reasons. First, the number
  • 6:46 - 6:52
    of people who are freed on net goes down -
    we don't get as big a drop in the quantity
  • 6:52 - 6:57
    of slaves demanded because the price
    doesn't go up as much. The second reason,
  • 6:57 - 7:03
    however, is that in order to get that net
    freed, we've actually created more slaves,
  • 7:03 - 7:08
    we've actually created more people who are
    captured. So at the end of the day, 400
  • 7:08 - 7:14
    people are still freed. On net, fewer
    people end up being slaves at the end of
  • 7:15 - 7:21
    the day, but to get there at the beginning
    of the day, we've got a lot more people who
  • 7:21 - 7:28
    are enslaved, who were taken by the slave
    traders. So this makes it very difficult.
  • 7:28 - 7:33
    The more elastic the supply curve is, the
    less successful the program can be and the
  • 7:33 - 7:38
    more of these terrible, terrible trade-
    offs that there are. And if we remember
  • 7:38 - 7:43
    some of the facts about elasticity in
    particular, remember supply curves get
  • 7:43 - 7:48
    more elastic in the long run, well that's
    exactly what we saw in the case in the
  • 7:48 - 7:54
    Sudan. At the beginning, the redemption
    program increased the price of slaves a
  • 7:54 - 8:00
    lot, but as the supply curve became more
    elastic over time, the price of slaves
  • 8:01 - 8:05
    began to fall back down again. It was not
    increased by as much.
  • 8:05 - 8:12
    And thus this redemption program became
    less successful over time. So this is a
  • 8:13 - 8:18
    very tricky issue. It's a very
    controversial issue. Did the groups like
  • 8:18 - 8:21
    Christian Solidarity International - were
    they on net helpful? There are these
  • 8:22 - 8:27
    terrible trade-offs. Economics can't
    answer this question, but it can at least
  • 8:27 - 8:35
    point to the supply response and what that
    means in moral terms. Let's look at
  • 8:35 - 8:40
    another application. Let's look at another
    important question which we can analyze
  • 8:40 - 8:44
    using demand and supply. What is the
    effect of gun buybacks? Now these
  • 8:44 - 8:49
    buybacks are often sponsored by local
    governments, the local police, the local
  • 8:49 - 8:55
    mayor and so forth. In this buyback which
    was held in Oakland, the officials offered
  • 8:55 - 9:00
    $250 cash for each working gun, no
    questions asked. They then collected the
  • 9:00 - 9:05
    guns and they melted them down. The idea
    was to get guns off the street. They ended
  • 9:05 - 9:10
    up collecting about 500 guns in this
    buyback. These buybacks are often held.
  • 9:10 - 9:14
    There's been one in Washington, D.C. and
    Rochester, New York, and throughout the
  • 9:14 - 9:19
    United States. They're fairly common again
    at the local level. The question is, can
  • 9:19 - 9:24
    these buybacks be effective? And to answer
    that we need to make some assumptions or
  • 9:24 - 9:29
    we need to know something about demand and
    supply. In particular, what assumptions
  • 9:29 - 9:36
    would make sense about the elasticity of
    supply? Is the supply curve of guns to a
  • 9:36 - 9:40
    city like Washington, D.C. or Oakland,
    California, is that supply curve going to
  • 9:41 - 9:49
    be inelastic or elastic? Bear in mind what
    that means. So we're looking at the
  • 9:49 - 9:57
    elasticity of supply of guns in a city
    like Washington, D.C. or a town. Also bear
  • 9:57 - 10:02
    in mind that in the United States as a whole,
    there are hundreds of millions of guns, and
  • 10:02 - 10:08
    that guns continue to be produced,
    manufactured, bought and sold every day.
  • 10:08 - 10:14
    So what assumptions would you make about
    the local supply curve of guns in a city
  • 10:14 - 10:21
    like Washington, D.C.? Think about that.
    I'll give you an answer on the next slide.
  • 10:21 - 10:27
    The supply of guns to a local region is
    going to be very elastic. Remember our
  • 10:27 - 10:34
    earlier example of suppose that we have an
    increase in demand for gasoline in
  • 10:34 - 10:38
    Washington, D.C. - is that going to increase
    the price of gasoline in Washington, D.C.?
  • 10:39 - 10:46
    The answer is no because just a tiny
    increase in price and lots of gasoline
  • 10:46 - 10:50
    will come in from Virginia, from Maryland,
    from other states in the country.
  • 10:50 - 10:57
    Remember, the more local the supply, the
    more elastic the supply curve. So an
  • 10:57 - 11:02
    increase in the demand for gasoline in
    Washington, D.C. - that's not going to
  • 11:02 - 11:07
    increase the world price of gasoline. And
    it's not even going to increase the price
  • 11:07 - 11:12
    of gasoline in Washington, D.C., because if
    it did people would start to sell gas in
  • 11:12 - 11:17
    Washington, D.C. instead of next door, in
    Virginia or Maryland. So the price has
  • 11:17 - 11:21
    got to be about the same throughout the
    United States. The same thing is true for
  • 11:21 - 11:27
    guns. The supply of guns to a local region
    like Oakland or Washington, D.C. is going
  • 11:27 - 11:33
    to be very elastic. That has surprising
    facts. It means that local buybacks won't
  • 11:34 - 11:39
    affect the number of guns on the street
    nor even their price. Let's take a look at
  • 11:40 - 11:48
    the diagram. Here is our demand curve for
    guns. Here's our supply curve, which is
  • 11:48 - 11:53
    drawn very elastic because it's a local
    market. The initial equilibrium is at
  • 11:53 - 11:57
    point A at a certain price of guns and a
    certain quantity of guns traded each
  • 11:57 - 12:00
    period. What the buyback does is
  • 12:00 - 12:04
    it increases the demand for guns,
    shifting the equilibrium
  • 12:04 - 12:08
    to point B.
    So the buyback, they end up buying a lot of
  • 12:08 - 12:13
    guns, but all of the guns they end up
    buying come from the increase in the
  • 12:14 - 12:20
    quantity supplied. Notice that the buyback
    doesn't push the price of guns up. Because
  • 12:20 - 12:25
    it doesn't push the price of guns up, no
    one stops buying a gun. Remember, a
  • 12:25 - 12:32
    buyback is going to be effective only if
    it makes guns more expensive, only if it
  • 12:32 - 12:34
    reduces the quantity demanded of guns.
  • 12:34 - 12:39
    Since all of the increase in supply
    is being generated by
  • 12:39 - 12:43
    the buyback itself, the buyback doesn't
    increase the price of guns in Washington,
  • 12:43 - 12:47
    D.C., therefore it doesn't reduce the
    quantity demanded of guns in Washington,
  • 12:47 - 12:53
    D.C., therefore no effect on the number of
    guns held. Now in particular what's going
  • 12:53 - 12:59
    to happen is that if the mayor offers $250
    for a gun, people are going to go into
  • 13:00 - 13:03
    their closet, they're going to find an old
    low-quality gun, a gun they don't really
  • 13:03 - 13:08
    want. They're going to turn that in and
    maybe a few weeks or a few months later,
  • 13:08 - 13:13
    they're going to buy a new gun. Think
    about it this way. Imagine for whatever
  • 13:13 - 13:18
    odd reason that the government in
    Washington, D.C. wanted to reduce the
  • 13:18 - 13:25
    number of people wearing sneakers so they
    offered a sneaker buyback. For $50 they
  • 13:25 - 13:31
    would buy any pair of sneakers - no
    questions asked. Well, of course people
  • 13:31 - 13:34
    are going to go into their closet, they're
    going to find old pairs of sneakers they
  • 13:34 - 13:37
    don't really want anymore and they're
    going to turn those in. They're going to
  • 13:37 - 13:42
    sell, they're going to sell those sneakers
    to the government. But is anyone in
  • 13:43 - 13:48
    Washington, D.C. going to end up in the
    long run going shoeless, even going
  • 13:48 - 13:53
    sneaker-less? No. They may turn their
    sneakers in, but a few weeks, a few months
  • 13:53 - 13:57
    later they're going to be buying a new
    pair of sneakers. We haven't changed the
  • 13:57 - 14:01
    price of sneakers, therefore we haven't
    changed the quantity demanded of sneakers,
  • 14:02 - 14:05
    therefore we're going to stay at the
    equilibrium.
  • 14:05 - 14:11
    Once the buyback is over, we're going to be
    at the same equilibrium at point A. So
  • 14:11 - 14:18
    local gun buybacks don't work. They're
    really in my view a waste of time. This
  • 14:19 - 14:22
    doesn't mean that we can't do anything. We
    may want to put more police on the street,
  • 14:23 - 14:27
    we may want to fight crime in other ways,
    but a local gun buyback isn't going to
  • 14:27 - 14:34
    work. Another point, a few countries, such
    as Australia, that had required buybacks,
  • 14:34 - 14:39
    mandatory buybacks, where they ban guns and
    then buy them back. Well, since that's, A
  • 14:39 - 14:44
    Mandatory, and B for the country as a
    whole, that might get guns off the street,
  • 14:44 - 14:51
    but here we're talking about a local
    buyback. And because of the elasticity of
  • 14:52 - 14:56
    supply, it's not going to affect the number
    of guns on the local streets nor even
  • 14:57 - 15:03
    their price and thus it's going to be, in
    my view, completely ineffective. It's
  • 15:03 - 15:08
    really quite amazing how a little bit of
    economics can go a long way to
  • 15:08 - 15:14
    understanding and improving public policy.
    Hopefully you see the argument about the
  • 15:15 - 15:19
    elasticity of supply of guns and yet we
    see these policies being passed all the
  • 15:19 - 15:24
    time, these ineffective policies are
    actually often put into place. A little
  • 15:24 - 15:28
    bit of economics goes a long way to
    improving public policy, if only we can
  • 15:28 - 15:34
    get the message out. Okay, thanks very
    much. See you, uh, next chapter.
  • 15:36 - 15:41
    - [Announcer] If you want to test yourself,
    click “Practice Questions.” Or, if you're
  • 15:41 - 15:44
    ready to move on, just click “Next Video.”
  • 15:44 - 15:46
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
Applications Using Elasticity
Description:

In this video, we take a look at real-world applications of elasticity, using the examples of slave redemption in Sudan and and the effects of gun buyback programs in the U.S.

Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/elasticity-examples-applications#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/taxes-subsidies-definition-tax-wedge

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
15:49

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions