Return to Video

Arguments Against International trade

  • Not Synced
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • Not Synced
    - [Alex] In our previous videos,
    we explained the benefits of trade.
  • Not Synced
    Today we're going to evaluate
    some of the arguments
  • Not Synced
    that one often hears
    about limiting international trade.
  • Not Synced
    International trade is
    a controversial subject.
  • Not Synced
    There are a lot of arguments
    surrounding it.
  • Not Synced
    We're not going to go through all
    of them by any means.
  • Not Synced
    But here are some
    of the most common:
  • Not Synced
    That trade reduces the number
    of jobs in the United States.
  • Not Synced
    That it's wrong to trade
    with countries that use child labor.
  • Not Synced
    That we need to keep certain jobs at home
    for national security.
  • Not Synced
    We need to keep certain key industries at
    home because of beneficial spillovers onto
  • Not Synced
    other sectors of the economy.
    And we can increase US well-being, the
  • Not Synced
    argument goes, with strategic trade
    protectionism.
  • Not Synced
    So we're going to evaluate, say a few
    things about each one of these arguments.
  • Not Synced
    Let's consider trade and jobs. What
    happens when a tariff is lowered? Well
  • Not Synced
    imports will increase, and there will be
    fewer jobs in the import competing
  • Not Synced
    industry. For example, if we have a tariff
    on shoes and we reduce the tariff, we'll
  • Not Synced
    have imports of more shoes from China and
    from Vietnam, and that will mean fewer
  • Not Synced
    jobs in the American shoe-producing
    industry.
  • Not Synced
    That's what people see when they think
    about reducing a tariff. They're worried
  • Not Synced
    about losing those jobs in the American
    industry. However, we want to see the
  • Not Synced
    issue in a deeper way, in a more
    fundamental way. And a key question to ask
  • Not Synced
    is, "Why do people send us goods? Why
    would workers in China, in Vietnam, work
  • Not Synced
    long hours to send us shoes?" It's
    certainly not from the kindness of their
  • Not Synced
    heart. Ultimately, they want goods in
    return, goods or services.
  • Not Synced
    They are working, they are producing in
    order to consume. They are sending us
  • Not Synced
    goods because they want goods in return.
    They are not doing it out of the goodness
  • Not Synced
    of their heart, but out of self-interest
    as Adam Smith said. And that leads to a
  • Not Synced
    fundamental insight about international
    trade. Namely, we pay for our imports with
  • Not Synced
    exports. When we import more, we will
    ultimately export more because we pay for
  • Not Synced
    our imports through our exports.
  • Not Synced
    What this means is that trade doesn't
    destroy jobs overall. Trade moves jobs
  • Not Synced
    from import-competing industries to export
    industries. And overall, wages increase on
  • Not Synced
    average because of comparative advantage.
    Because we pay for our imports with
  • Not Synced
    exports, when we import more, we will
    export more. Jobs will reduce in the
  • Not Synced
    import-competing industries and increase
    in the export industries.
  • Not Synced
    Now, this process is not always easy.
    Problems can occur when we lose jobs in
  • Not Synced
    low-skill import-competing sectors and
    gain jobs in high-skill export sectors.
  • Not Synced
    Overall, when the United States imports
    goods, we typically import goods produced
  • Not Synced
    by low-skill, because America on average
    is a high-skill economy, has high-skilled
  • Not Synced
    workers on a world level. But we do have
    some low-skill workers, and imports tend
  • Not Synced
    to compete with the products produced by
    low-skilled workers.
  • Not Synced
    Everything will be fine if our education
    system is working well, and if those
  • Not Synced
    low-skill workers can increase their
    skills and move to high-tech, or
  • Not Synced
    high-skill, not necessarily high-tech,
    high-skill sectors.
  • Not Synced
    Of course, that's a big "if" and the
    transition can be difficult. We have to
  • Not Synced
    put this in context, however. In a growing
    economy, jobs are appearing and
  • Not Synced
    disappearing all the time. Not just or
    even fundamentally because of
  • Not Synced
    international trade, but because of
    changes in preferences and changes in
  • Not Synced
    technology.
    Let's take a look at that. It's important
  • Not Synced
    when thinking about trade and jobs and
    jobs in general that the American economy
  • Not Synced
    succeeds precisely because jobs are being
    created and destroyed all the time. Job
  • Not Synced
    destruction is often a sign of progress
    and growth. Think about Thomas Edison. He
  • Not Synced
    destroyed the whaling industry with his
    invention of the light bulb. CDs, some of
  • Not Synced
    you may not even remember Compact Discs,
    they destroyed jobs in the record
  • Not Synced
    industry. MP3s destroyed jobs in the CD
    industry. This is the way progress often
  • Not Synced
    occurs. Employment and the standard living
    overall keep rising over time, and the
  • Not Synced
    reason they're rising is precisely that
    old jobs are being destroyed, new jobs are
  • Not Synced
    being created. Overall, in the churn
    there's a trend towards richer jobs,
  • Not Synced
    higher-paying jobs, higher wages. Overall
    technology, trade, these benefit the US
  • Not Synced
    economy.
    Child labor is something which no one
  • Not Synced
    wants, but it's important to understand
    that child labor is something which
  • Not Synced
    happens when people are poor. Child labor
    was common in 19th century Great Britain
  • Not Synced
    and the United States. Child labor
    declined in the developed world as people
  • Not Synced
    got richer. Forces that reduced child
    labor in the developed world are also at
  • Not Synced
    work in the developing countries. As
    countries become richer, child labor
  • Not Synced
    declines.
  • Not Synced
    What this graph shows is that as real GDP
    per capita increases, the percent of
  • Not Synced
    children ages 10 to 14 in the labor force
    decreases. So increases in real GDP reduce
  • Not Synced
    the percent of children in the labor
    force. The circles, by the way, are
  • Not Synced
    proportional to the absolute number of
    children in the labor force, so in China
  • Not Synced
    for example, there are about 12 percent of
    kids in the labor force, but because there
  • Not Synced
    are so many Chinese children, that's a
    large number of children in absolute
  • Not Synced
    numbers.
    Again the key here is really that economic
  • Not Synced
    growth reduces child labor. So if you want
    to reduce child labor, you want a country
  • Not Synced
    to become rich. The question is, "Can one
    accelerate this process by banning child
  • Not Synced
    labor or by refusing to trade with
    countries that use child labor?" That's
  • Not Synced
    really refusing to trade with the poorest
    of countries. Do we really want to do
  • Not Synced
    that? Do we really want to say to poor
    countries, "We're not going to trade with
  • Not Synced
    you."
    There are many opportunities here for
  • Not Synced
    unintended consequences of laws which may
    have been, tried to do a good thing, but
  • Not Synced
    backfire. So for example, when India
    banned child labor, one of the effects of
  • Not Synced
    that was to reduce the wages of children
    because now you have to hire them under
  • Not Synced
    the table. Because their wages were lower,
    the families were poorer, and because the
  • Not Synced
    families were poorer, they had to rely
    even more on child labor. So it is very
  • Not Synced
    easy to create a policy which backfires.
    It is not, in my view, a good idea to use
  • Not Synced
    international trade as a weapon or as a
    tool against child labor.
  • Not Synced
    A much better idea would be to help poor
    countries, would be to offer free
  • Not Synced
    schooling in poor countries, to offer
    lunches for schools in poor countries.
  • Not Synced
    This increases the incentive to send the
    children to school because then they are
  • Not Synced
    fed. So there are lots of things we can do
    to reduce child labor in poorer countries,
  • Not Synced
    but to say to those countries, "We're not
    going to trade with you because you're
  • Not Synced
    poor and you're using child labor," just
    exactly the same way we did in the 19th
  • Not Synced
    century, that is really not in my view a
    productive policy.
  • Not Synced
    Trade and national security. Yeah, some
    industries probably should be protected to
  • Not Synced
    protect national security. The problem is
    this argument is subject to great abuse.
  • Not Synced
    Almost every industry can and does make
    the claim that they're essential for
  • Not Synced
    national security. So let's give some
    examples. Vaccine production? Yes,
  • Not Synced
    probably a good idea for us to have some
    domestic capability. We don't always want
  • Not Synced
    to buy our vaccines from abroad, just in
    case. Angora goat fleece? Am I serious?
  • Not Synced
    Yes. Believe it or not, we have protected
    Angora goats with the argument that their
  • Not Synced
    fleece is necessary to produce military
    uniforms. Yep, some people think goats are
  • Not Synced
    vital to national security. I'm not
    kidding.
  • Not Synced
    The key industries argument is very
    popular among the high-tech crowd. The
  • Not Synced
    argument is, is that there are some
    industries which for a variety of reasons
  • Not Synced
    are especially important for a nation to
    have a foothold in. "Biology, microbiology
  • Not Synced
    is going to be the future, therefore we
    need to have this type of industry." Or,
  • Not Synced
    'Computers are the future, therefore we
    need to have this type of industry." The
  • Not Synced
    argument is that these industries create
    spillovers for other industries. They
  • Not Synced
    create learning, they create research,
    they create workers, high-tech workers,
  • Not Synced
    which spread out to other areas of the
    economy and benefit the economy in ways
  • Not Synced
    which go beyond the GDP produced by those
    particular industries.
  • Not Synced
    Ross Perot famously made this argument
    when he said, "Producing computer chips is
  • Not Synced
    better than potato chips."
    In some ways this may be true, but it's
  • Not Synced
    overall not a compelling argument. For
    example, today most computer chips are
  • Not Synced
    cheap, mass-produced products. They're not
    something we really want to be producing
  • Not Synced
    at all. They're not even produced with a
    lot of labor. They're mostly produced in
  • Not Synced
    big factories which don't actually make a
    lot of money. Much better to design the
  • Not Synced
    product the way Apple does, making lots of
    profit, than to buy the chips which Apple
  • Not Synced
    uses in its iPhones, which don't make a lot
    of money at all.
  • Not Synced
    In 1990, Walmart contributed more to the
    boom in productivity than Silicon Valley.
  • Not Synced
    So it's always difficult to say exactly
    which are the most important industries.
  • Not Synced
    You wouldn't think that Walmart retail is
    a hugely important industry, and yet,
  • Not Synced
    Walmart is the world's largest firm and it
    has done a huge amount to make the
  • Not Synced
    American economy more productive. So no
    one really knows which industries are the
  • Not Synced
    ones with the really important spillovers,
    and when we add in political economy, the
  • Not Synced
    tendency for politics to often choose
    based upon the wrong reasons, this
  • Not Synced
    argument is really not very compelling.
    Here's an argument which again works in
  • Not Synced
    theory but is less likely to work in
    practice. It's possible for a country to
  • Not Synced
    use tariffs and quotas to get a larger
    share of the gains from trade. The
  • Not Synced
    argument here is that if you can limit or
    tax exports, not tax imports, but tax
  • Not Synced
    exports, then you can let domestic firms
    act as a cartel, so it's a way of helping
  • Not Synced
    domestic firms to be more like a monopoly,
    to act like a cartel. So the government
  • Not Synced
    plus the domestic firms put, creates a
    tax, or limits exports in order to raise
  • Not Synced
    the price of those exports on world
    markets and in order to grab up more of
  • Not Synced
    the gains from trade.
  • Not Synced
    It can work, especially if there are few
    substitutes for US-produced goods. On the
  • Not Synced
    other hand, if there are substitutes for
    US-produced goods or if we push the price
  • Not Synced
    of our goods up too high, and that creates
    the substitutes, we may in the long run
  • Not Synced
    really reduce our market. Moreover, these
    arguments for strategic trade
  • Not Synced
    protectionism are not such a great idea if
    other countries can retaliate. If every
  • Not Synced
    country tries to do this, then world trade
    as a whole will shrink and no country will
  • Not Synced
    be better off. So in trying to grab up a
    larger slice of the pie, we have to always
  • Not Synced
    be worried about making the pie smaller.
    Again, the argument works in theory. A
  • Not Synced
    very clever government might be able to do
    it, but in practice, this is really not a
  • Not Synced
    very good reason for limiting trade.
    So to sum up, restrictions on trade waste
  • Not Synced
    resources by transferring production from
    low-cost foreign producers to high-cost
  • Not Synced
    domestic producers. Restrictions on trade
    also prevent domestic consumers from
  • Not Synced
    exploiting all of the gains from trade.
    There are some good arguments for
  • Not Synced
    restricting trade. Some arguments are
    valid, but they're usually of limited
  • Not Synced
    applicability. Overall, I think free trade
    is a robust policy in the sense that it's a
  • Not Synced
    policy which works well in most
    circumstances and protectionism will work
  • Not Synced
    well only in a limited number of
    circumstances.
  • Not Synced
    Thanks!
  • Not Synced
    - [male] If you want to test yourself,
    click Practice Questions. Or, if you're
  • Not Synced
    ready move on, just click Next Video.
  • Not Synced
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
Arguments Against International trade
Description:

In this video, we discuss some of the most common arguments against international trade. Does trade harm workers by reducing the number of jobs in the U.S.? Is it wrong to trade with countries that use child labor? Is it important to keep a certain number of jobs at home for national security reasons? Can strategic protectionism increase well-being in the U.S.? Join us as we discuss these common concerns. - See more at: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/arguments-against-trade?

Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/arguments-against-trade#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/introduction-externalities

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
13:56

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions