Return to Video

Who Pays the Tax?

  • 0:03 - 0:05
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:09 - 0:13
    - In the last lecture, we showed that the
    legal incidence of a tax does not
  • 0:13 - 0:17
    determine the economic incidence. In this
    lecture, we're going to talk about how the
  • 0:18 - 0:22
    economic incidence of taxes actually is
    determined. Who bears the burden of
  • 0:22 - 0:23
    a tax?
  • 0:28 - 0:33
    Here is the rule for the economic
    incidence of a tax. The more elastic
  • 0:33 - 0:38
    side of the market will pay a smaller
    share of the tax, a smaller burden.
  • 0:38 - 0:43
    Similarly, the less elastic side of the
    market or rather the more inelastic side
  • 0:43 - 0:49
    of the market will pay a greater share of
    the tax. So more elastic pays a smaller
  • 0:49 - 0:54
    share, less elastic pays a greater share.
    I'm going to show you this in a couple of
  • 0:55 - 0:59
    diagrams and then give you the intuition
    for why it's the case. Let's suppose we
  • 0:59 - 1:04
    can't remember the rule. Is it the more
    elastic side which bears the smaller share
  • 1:04 - 1:08
    of the tax or the greater share of the
    tax? Say we can't quite remember. Well, no
  • 1:08 - 1:14
    problem. Let's just draw the diagram and
    read it off as it happens. For instance,
  • 1:14 - 1:18
    let's draw a diagram which has a pretty
    elastic demand curve and relatively
  • 1:18 - 1:24
    speaking a pretty inelastic supply curve.
    Here's the price when there's no tax. Now
  • 1:24 - 1:29
    let's look at what happens when there is a
    tax and we'll use our wedge method. Here's
  • 1:29 - 1:34
    the tax and the height of the wedge gives
    us the amount of the tax. What do we do?
  • 1:34 - 1:39
    We drive this wedge into the diagram until
    the top of it hits the demand curve and
  • 1:39 - 1:43
    the bottom of it hits the supply curve and
    then we just read the answer off our
  • 1:43 - 1:49
    diagram. Point B, this tells us the price
    paid by the buyer. Point D, this tells us
  • 1:49 - 1:55
    the price received by the seller. Let's
    compare. When there was no tax, the price
  • 1:55 - 1:59
    paid by the buyer was at A and with the
    tax the price to the buyer goes up a
  • 1:59 - 2:03
    little bit to point B.
    The buyer isn't paying much of a higher
  • 2:03 - 2:08
    price. On the other hand the seller is
    receiving a lot less. In this case, when
  • 2:08 - 2:13
    demand is more elastic than supply, the
    demanders pay a smaller share of the tax
  • 2:14 - 2:19
    and the suppliers pay a larger share.
    Therefore we can just read off the diagram
  • 2:19 - 2:23
    what happens when demand is more elastic
    than supply. You don't have to remember
  • 2:24 - 2:27
    the rule, you don't have to memorize it
    because I'm going to give you some
  • 2:27 - 2:31
    intuition to make it easy in just a
    moment. You simply have to draw the
  • 2:31 - 2:37
    diagram and be able to read the answer off
    the curves. Let's look at another case. In
  • 2:37 - 2:41
    this case, we've drawn a supply curve
    which is very inelastic and a demand curve
  • 2:41 - 2:45
    which is less elastic than the supply
    curve. Once again we're going to take our
  • 2:46 - 2:50
    tax wedge, we're going to push it into the
    diagram and what happens? You can see it
  • 2:50 - 2:55
    right here. We just have to read it off
    the diagram. Now we see that compared to
  • 2:55 - 2:59
    when there was no tax, the price to the
    buyer has gone up a lot and the price to
  • 3:00 - 3:05
    the sellers has gone down by just a little
    bit. When the supply is more elastic than
  • 3:05 - 3:09
    demand, buyers pay the greater share of
    the tax, that is the price to the buyer
  • 3:10 - 3:15
    goes up more than the price to the sellers
    goes down. The buyers pay more of the tax
  • 3:15 - 3:19
    when the supply curve is more elastic.
    Let's give some intuition. You can always
  • 3:20 - 3:23
    get the right answer by drawing the
    curves. And let's consider the intuition
  • 3:23 - 3:28
    for why that's the case. So here's the
    intuition for remembering the rule. Think
  • 3:28 - 3:33
    about elasticity as a kind of escape. The
    side of the market which is the more
  • 3:33 - 3:39
    elastic can escape the tax more easily.
    Why does that makes sense? Remember what
  • 3:39 - 3:43
    elastic demand means. It means that
    demanders have good substitutes for the
  • 3:43 - 3:48
    taxed good and so they can escape the tax.
    When the tax is high, the demanders are
  • 3:48 - 3:52
    going to say, "We're just going to go buy
    the substitutes. We have plenty of good
  • 3:52 - 3:56
    substitutes." On the other hand, think
    about what it means when the demand is
  • 3:56 - 4:02
    inelastic. It means that there are no good
    substitutes so it's hard to escape to tax.
  • 4:02 - 4:07
    What about the supply side, elastic
    supply? Well, that means the resources
  • 4:07 - 4:10
    which are used to produce the taxed good,
    they can easily be moved to other
  • 4:11 - 4:16
    industries. The resources can move around
    easily. If you try to tax the industry a
  • 4:16 - 4:20
    lot then the land, the capital, the
    workers in that industry which were used
  • 4:20 - 4:24
    to produce the good, they're just going to
    flow to other industries and so the
  • 4:24 - 4:29
    suppliers can relatively easily escape the
    tax. On the other hand, if supply is
  • 4:30 - 4:34
    inelastic that means the resources used to
    produce this good, they really can only be
  • 4:35 - 4:39
    used to produce this good. They're fixed,
    they're hard to move around, and those
  • 4:39 - 4:43
    factors are not that useful for producing
    other goods, so that makes it difficult
  • 4:44 - 4:48
    for the suppliers when the supply curve is
    inelastic. That means it's difficult for
  • 4:48 - 4:53
    the suppliers to escape the tax. What if
    the demanders and the suppliers are both
  • 4:54 - 4:58
    pretty elastic? Well, here's the thing.
    Somebody has to pay the tax, both sides
  • 4:59 - 5:03
    can't escape the tax at least if the good
    is going to be bought and sold, therefore
  • 5:03 - 5:09
    the burden is determined by the relative
    elasticities. It's about which side has it
  • 5:09 - 5:14
    easier to escape the tax and that side
    will pay less of the tax. The side which
  • 5:14 - 5:19
    is less elastic, they're going to pay more
    of the tax because that side finds it
  • 5:19 - 5:26
    harder to escape the tax. So let's do an
    application, say social security taxes.
  • 5:26 - 5:31
    Last time we showed that the legal
    incidence of social security taxes has no
  • 5:31 - 5:35
    bearing on the economic incidence but we
    didn't say what the economic incidence
  • 5:35 - 5:40
    actually is. So let's do that now. We're
    going to have the price of labor up here,
  • 5:40 - 5:46
    the wage, and the quantity of labor down
    here. The whole question now boils down to
  • 5:46 - 5:51
    is the demand for labor, more elastic than
    the supply of labor or vice versa? Think
  • 5:51 - 5:56
    about the demanders of labor, businesses,
    what substitutes for labor do they have?
  • 5:56 - 6:00
    If the price of labor goes up, what can
    those businesses do?
  • 6:00 - 6:04
    What about the supply of labor, the
    workers? If their wage goes down, what can
  • 6:05 - 6:09
    they do? If you think about it I think
    you'll see that for most workers,
  • 6:09 - 6:13
    especially full time workers, they don't
    really have a lot of good substitutes for
  • 6:13 - 6:19
    work. Most workers need some kind of job.
    Even if their wage goes down they're going
  • 6:19 - 6:23
    to continue to work because they need to
    pay the bills. On the other hand, the
  • 6:24 - 6:28
    demanders of labor if the wage were to go
    up, they could substitute capital for
  • 6:29 - 6:33
    labor, they could move their investments
    to other countries. They have quite a few
  • 6:33 - 6:37
    good substitutes. So if that's actually
    how it works we should probably draw the
  • 6:37 - 6:42
    diagram like this with a fairly inelastic
    supply of labor and a fairly elastic
  • 6:42 - 6:47
    demand for labor. Economists have done
    studies of this and on average this is
  • 6:47 - 6:53
    what they find. So now think about your
    FICA taxes, that's a tax on labor. What's
  • 6:53 - 6:57
    the effect of that? Well, it's going to
    look something like this. Notice that the
  • 6:57 - 7:02
    wage paid by buyers of labor, that's the
    wage paid by the firms that goes up only a
  • 7:02 - 7:07
    little bit. On the other hand, the wage
    received by the suppliers of labor, that
  • 7:07 - 7:12
    is the wage which the workers end up with,
    that goes down by a lot. And this makes
  • 7:12 - 7:17
    perfect sense when we have a very
    inelastic supply of labor. The laborers
  • 7:17 - 7:21
    can't escape the tax and therefore they
    end up bearing most of the burden of the
  • 7:21 - 7:27
    tax. This doesn't mean by the way that we
    shouldn't have social security taxes. It
  • 7:27 - 7:31
    may in fact be a good way of forcing
    people to save for their own future but
  • 7:31 - 7:35
    this does mean it is not a free lunch for
    the workers. The workers' wages will
  • 7:35 - 7:40
    drop because of the tax. If we didn't
    have the social security tax, wages for
  • 7:40 - 7:45
    most workers would in fact be higher.
    Here's one more application, health
  • 7:45 - 7:50
    insurance mandates. Suppose that the
    government requires employers to provide
  • 7:50 - 7:54
    health insurance to their workers as is
    now the case for many employers under the
  • 7:54 - 7:59
    Affordable Care Act. Who's going to pay
    for this? Who will end up paying for this?
  • 7:59 - 8:03
    Is it primarily the employers or primarily
    the workers?
  • 8:03 - 8:08
    It's really just the same analysis as we
    had before. A health insurance mandate is
  • 8:08 - 8:13
    quite similar to a tax. A health insurance
    mandate simply means that the employers
  • 8:13 - 8:19
    have to pay a higher wage but that's just
    then the same as the tax. What we just saw
  • 8:19 - 8:24
    is that if labor supply is less elastic
    than labor demand, which in many cases
  • 8:24 - 8:29
    makes sense, then in that case most of the
    mandate will actually be paid for by the
  • 8:29 - 8:35
    workers. Real wages will fall. Again this
    doesn't necessarily mean that the mandate
  • 8:35 - 8:39
    is a bad idea but it does mean it's not a
    free lunch for the workers. The workers
  • 8:39 - 8:44
    end up paying for their health care
    through the medium of lower wages. Taxes
  • 8:44 - 8:49
    have a couple of other effects including
    the raising of revenue and also creating
  • 8:49 - 8:52
    some dead weight loss. Those are what
    we're going to look at in the next
  • 8:53 - 8:53
    lecture.
  • 8:55 - 8:59
    - [male] If you want to test yourself,
    click Practice questions. Or if you're
  • 8:59 - 9:02
    ready to move on, just click Next Video.
  • 9:03 - 9:05
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
Who Pays the Tax?
Description:

Who bears the burden of a tax? Buyers or sellers? Why is it that the more elastic side of the market will pay a smaller share of a tax. Again, we’ll apply what we know to the example of Social Security taxes and also look at the health insurance mandate as a part of the Affordable Care Act. Who pays for the mandate? The employers or the workers? We’ll also look at supply and demand of labor. Is the demand for labor more elastic than the supply?
Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/tax-burden-elasticity-affordable-care-act-health-insurance-mandate#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/deadweight-loss-definition-yacht-tax

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
09:07
Martel Espiritu edited English subtitles for Who Pays the Tax?
Martel Espiritu edited English subtitles for Who Pays the Tax?
Martel Espiritu edited English subtitles for Who Pays the Tax?
MRU2 edited English subtitles for Who Pays the Tax?
MRU2 edited English subtitles for Who Pays the Tax?

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions