Return to Video

Maximizing Profit under Competition

  • 0:00 - 0:03
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:10 - 0:14
    - We learned last time that a firm in a
    competitive market doesn't have much
  • 0:14 - 0:20
    control over it's price. It must accept
    the market price. So its decision about
  • 0:20 - 0:27
    profit maximization turns into a decision
    about what quantity to choose, and that's
  • 0:27 - 0:29
    what we're going to
    be focusing on now.
  • 0:34 - 0:37
    - So what is profit?
    Profit is total revenue
  • 0:37 - 0:43
    minus total cost. Total revenue is just
    price times the quantity sold. Total cost
  • 0:43 - 0:50
    has two parts. First are the fixed costs.
    These are costs that do not vary with
  • 0:50 - 0:56
    output. So, for example, suppose you are
    the owner of this small oil well and you
  • 0:57 - 1:03
    have to pay rent for the land on which the
    oil well sits. Those rental costs - you have
  • 1:03 - 1:09
    to pay them regardless of how much the oil
    well is producing. Every month you have to
  • 1:09 - 1:14
    pay some rental cost whether you're
    producing one barrel of oil per month, 10
  • 1:15 - 1:19
    barrels of oil per month, 11 barrels of
    oil per month… It doesn't matter. You still
  • 1:19 - 1:24
    have to pay the same rental cost. Indeed,
    even if you don't produce any oil that
  • 1:24 - 1:29
    month, if your oil well breaks down, you
    still have to pay those rental costs. So
  • 1:29 - 1:35
    the rental costs are fixed costs. They
    don't vary with the quantity produced. By
  • 1:35 - 1:40
    the way, notice that even if you owned the
    land, if you could have rented it to
  • 1:41 - 1:47
    someone else, then that would be an
    opportunity cost. So your calculation of
  • 1:47 - 1:54
    profit should also include opportunity
    costs. That's what makes the economic
  • 1:54 - 1:59
    calculation of profit, by the way, differ by
    the accounting definition of profit. The
  • 1:59 - 2:03
    economic notion of profit
    includes opportunity costs.
  • 2:03 - 2:10
    Okay, what else? Well, variable costs - these
    are the cost that do vary with output. So
  • 2:10 - 2:15
    for example, the electricity cost for
    pumping oil - the more oil you pump, the
  • 2:15 - 2:21
    faster you get your rig to go, the more
    electricity you're going to use up. If you
  • 2:21 - 2:25
    run it 24 hours a day, you're going to use
    more electricity than if you only run the
  • 2:25 - 2:30
    pump 12 hours a day. Transportation cost -
    you got to go and get the oil, truck it
  • 2:31 - 2:36
    out of there, move it and so forth. So
    these costs are all costs which vary with
  • 2:36 - 2:41
    output, which typically will increase the
    more output that you produce. Those are
  • 2:41 - 2:48
    your variable costs. So just to summarize
    on cost, total cost is equal to your fixed
  • 2:48 - 2:54
    costs plus your variable costs and these
    depend upon output. Okay, so how do we
  • 2:55 - 3:00
    maximize profit? Well, we're not going to
    use calculus in this class, but for those
  • 3:00 - 3:04
    of you who do know calculus I want to do
    a quick aside - show you actually how useful
  • 3:04 - 3:08
    calculus is and show you an easy way of
    answering this problem. So we know the
  • 3:09 - 3:13
    profit is total revenue minus total cost
    and both of these are functions of the
  • 3:14 - 3:19
    quantity produced. Now in calculus how do
    we maximize a function? Think back to your
  • 3:19 - 3:25
    calculus class. You take the derivative of
    that function and you set it equal to
  • 3:26 - 3:30
    zero. So in this case we want to take the
    derivative of profit with respect to
  • 3:30 - 3:35
    quantity and set that equal to zero. So
    derivative of profit respect to quantity -
  • 3:36 - 3:41
    that's just the derivative of total
    revenue with respect to quantity minus
  • 3:41 - 3:46
    the derivative of total cost with respect
    to quantity. Now in economics we have
  • 3:46 - 3:50
    special names for these two derivatives.
    The derivative of total revenue with
  • 3:50 - 3:55
    respect to quantity is simply called
    marginal revenue. And the derivative of
  • 3:55 - 4:00
    total cost with respect to quantity is
    called marginal cost. So we want to find
  • 4:01 - 4:05
    the quantity such that marginal revenue
    minus marginal cost is zero, or in other
  • 4:06 - 4:10
    words, we want to find
    the quantity such that marginal
  • 4:10 - 4:16
    revenue is equal to marginal cost. In
    other words, the quantity, which maximizes
  • 4:16 - 4:22
    profit, is the one where marginal
    revenue is equal to marginal cost. Now I'm
  • 4:22 - 4:26
    about to give you a more intuitive
    explanation, especially for those of you
  • 4:26 - 4:31
    who don't get no calculus, but for those of
    you who do, this is just exactly what you
  • 4:32 - 4:35
    were to do in calculus - you take the
    derivative set it equal to zero. Okay
  • 4:36 - 4:40
    let's get some more intuition. When the
    firm produces an additional unit of
  • 4:40 - 4:47
    output, there are additional revenues and
    additional costs. Profit maximization is
  • 4:47 - 4:52
    all about comparing these additional
    revenues and costs, and we have names for
  • 4:52 - 4:58
    these. Marginal revenue is the addition to
    total revenue from selling an additional
  • 4:58 - 5:05
    unit of output. Marginal cost is the
    addition to total cost from producing an
  • 5:05 - 5:10
    additional unit of output. Profits are
    maximized at the level of output where
  • 5:10 - 5:14
    marginal revenue is equal to marginal
    cost. Now why is this? Well, let's
  • 5:14 - 5:19
    suppose that marginal revenue is not
    equal to marginal cost and let’s show that
  • 5:19 - 5:24
    you can't be profit maximizing if that's
    the case. For example, if marginal revenue
  • 5:25 - 5:29
    is bigger than marginal cost you're not
    profit maximizing - producing more will add
  • 5:30 - 5:36
    to your profit. Why? Well, remember
    marginal revenue is the addition to
  • 5:36 - 5:42
    revenue from producing another unit.
    Marginal cost is the addition to cost from
  • 5:42 - 5:46
    producing another unit. If marginal
    revenue is bigger than marginal cost, that
  • 5:46 - 5:52
    says producing that unit adds more to your
    revenues than it does to your costs. In
  • 5:52 - 5:58
    other words, you could increase profit by
    producing more. So if marginal revenue is
  • 5:58 - 6:03
    ever bigger than marginal cost,
    you want to produce more. On
  • 6:03 - 6:08
    the other hand, suppose marginal revenue
    is less than marginal cost, or to put it
  • 6:08 - 6:13
    the other way, suppose marginal cost is
    bigger than marginal revenue. Well then,
  • 6:14 - 6:20
    you're not profit maximizing because
    producing less will add to your profit.
  • 6:20 - 6:28
    Why is this? Well, think about marginal
    cost. If you were to produce one unit less
  • 6:28 - 6:35
    your costs would fall by marginal cost,
    your revenues would also fall by marginal
  • 6:35 - 6:41
    Revenue, but since marginal cost is bigger
    than marginal revenue, your costs by
  • 6:41 - 6:47
    producing one unit less fall by more than
    your revenues fall. So if your costs are
  • 6:47 - 6:53
    going down by more than your revenues are
    going down, you're again increasing
  • 6:53 - 6:59
    profit. So if marginal revenue is ever
    less than marginal cost, you want to
  • 6:59 - 7:06
    produce less - you'll be increasing your
    profit by producing less. So, if marginal
  • 7:07 - 7:11
    revenue is bigger than marginal cost,
    you're not profit maximizing. If marginal
  • 7:11 - 7:17
    revenue is less than marginal cost you're
    not profit maximizing. You can only profit
  • 7:17 - 7:24
    maximize if marginal revenue is equal to
    marginal cost. Now let's put all this in
  • 7:24 - 7:29
    a diagram beginning with marginal revenue.
    Now for a competitive firm this is going
  • 7:29 - 7:34
    to be easy because remember, that a
    competitive firm is small relative to the
  • 7:34 - 7:41
    total market. That means it can double its
    production easily and not push down the
  • 7:42 - 7:47
    market price. As a result, for a
    competitive firm, marginal revenue is equal
  • 7:48 - 7:53
    to the market price. So for example,
    suppose the firm is producing two units of
  • 7:53 - 7:58
    output and it decides to produce a third
    unit, what's the additional revenue from
  • 7:58 - 8:03
    that third unit? It's the price. It's the
    price it gets for that barrel of oil.
  • 8:03 - 8:07
    What about if it produces a fourth
    barrel of oil? What does it get? What's
  • 8:07 - 8:11
    the addition to revenue? It's the price of
    a barrel of oil. What about the fifth
  • 8:12 - 8:19
    unit? Again, the price is the addition to
    revenue, is marginal revenue. So, marginal
  • 8:19 - 8:24
    revenue for a competitive firm is equal to
    the price and it's flat - it doesn't change
  • 8:24 - 8:29
    when the firm changes its output because
    the firm is small relative to the market.
  • 8:29 - 8:34
    Now what about marginal cost? Well, a
    typical shape of a marginal cost curve
  • 8:34 - 8:39
    would be upward sloping like this. Again,
    think about our stripper oil well. We can
  • 8:40 - 8:46
    produce more from that oil well, but
    there's a limit. We can only run it so
  • 8:46 - 8:51
    quickly. We have to push it really hard
    when we start to produce more. So we can
  • 8:51 - 8:55
    easily produce you know, three or four
    units, but in order to produce six, seven,
  • 8:56 - 9:01
    eight or nine barrels of oil from that oil
    well, we're going to have to run it really
  • 9:01 - 9:04
    quickly, we're going to have to put in a
    lot of electricity, we're going to have to
  • 9:04 - 9:11
    do a lot of maintenance and so forth. So
    our costs will tend to increase. We can't
  • 9:11 - 9:17
    produce an unlimited amount of oil at the
    same cost from this oil well. Our costs
  • 9:17 - 9:23
    are going to go up, are going to rise, our additional
    costs are going to rise the more we want to
  • 9:23 - 9:30
    produce from that oil well. So this is a
    typical shape of a marginal cost curve.
  • 9:30 - 9:35
    Now, where's profit maximization? Well,
    profit is maximized where marginal revenue
  • 9:35 - 9:39
    is equal to marginal cost. In this case,
    for a competitive firm, marginal
  • 9:39 - 9:44
    revenue is equal to price. So profit is
    maximized where price is equal to marginal
  • 9:44 - 9:52
    cost or at this point right here. Now
    let's think about that intuitively. On the
  • 9:52 - 9:58
    left hand side this is the additional
    revenues from selling a barrel of oil.
  • 9:58 - 10:01
    These are the additional costs
    from selling a barrel of oil.
  • 10:01 - 10:07
    So you want to compare - revenues bigger
    than costs, therefore sell more. Revenues
  • 10:07 - 10:11
    bigger than costs, therefore sell more.
    Revenues bigger than costs. You keep
  • 10:11 - 10:17
    selling more until you reach this point.
    Do you want to go further? No. Here, costs
  • 10:17 - 10:24
    are bigger than revenues. So by selling
    less, you can reduce your costs by more
  • 10:24 - 10:29
    than you'd reduce your revenues and therefore
    profit goes up going this way and
  • 10:29 - 10:34
    that's why this point, where marginal
    revenue is equal to marginal cost, or price
  • 10:34 - 10:39
    is equal to marginal cost, that's the
    point where profit is maximized. Now
  • 10:39 - 10:45
    remember way back in the first talk, we
    wanted to explain a firm’s behavior. So
  • 10:45 - 10:50
    let's look how maximizing profit explains
    the firm’s behavior. Suppose the market
  • 10:50 - 10:57
    price is $50 per barrel. Well, then in
    order to maximize profit, the firm chooses
  • 10:57 - 11:02
    the quantity - in this case, about eight
    barrels of oil - such that marginal revenue
  • 11:02 - 11:04
    is equal to marginal
    cost, bearing in mind
  • 11:04 - 11:07
    that for the competitive
    firm, marginal revenue is equal
  • 11:07 - 11:12
    to price. So to profit maximize the firm
    produces a quantity of about eight barrels
  • 11:13 - 11:19
    of oil. Now suppose that the market price
    goes up to $100. Now in order to profit
  • 11:19 - 11:27
    maximize, the firm increases its production
    along its marginal cost curve keeping this
  • 11:28 - 11:32
    relationship the same so price is still
    equal to marginal cost. Price has gone up
  • 11:33 - 11:38
    to 100, but because the firm has expanded
    along its marginal cost curve, marginal
  • 11:38 - 11:44
    cost has gone up as well. So this again
    is the profit maximizing point when the
  • 11:45 - 11:49
    price is equal to 100. When the price is
    equal to 100 the profit maximizing
  • 11:49 - 11:56
    quantity is just under 10 barrels of oil.
    So profit maximization explains what the
  • 11:56 - 12:01
    firm does when the price, when
    the market price, changes.
  • 12:01 - 12:06
    We now know how to find the profit
    maximizing quantity - look for the quantity
  • 12:06 - 12:10
    where marginal revenue is equal to
    marginal cost, which is the same for the
  • 12:10 - 12:15
    competitive firm where price is equal to
    marginal cost. Now we want to ask, what is
  • 12:16 - 12:21
    the size of the profit? This raises a
    subtle point. You can be maximizing
  • 12:21 - 12:27
    profits and actually have a loss. That is,
    the best that you can do might be a loss.
  • 12:27 - 12:32
    So we want to show on the diagram how
    large your profits or how large your
  • 12:32 - 12:37
    losses are when you are maximizing
    profits. In order to do that we need to
  • 12:37 - 12:42
    introduce another concept and another
    curve - average cost. Average cost is
  • 12:43 - 12:47
    simply the cost per unit of output. That
    is the total cost divided by Q, the
  • 12:48 - 12:53
    quantity of the output. So average cost
    again - total cost divided by Q. Adding the
  • 12:54 - 12:59
    average cost curve to our graph will let
    us show profit on the graph. And that's
  • 12:59 - 13:02
    what we want to do, and that's what
    we'll do in the next talk. Thanks.
  • 13:04 - 13:08
    - [Announcer] If you want to test
    yourself, click, "Practice Questions," or
  • 13:08 - 13:11
    if you're ready to move on,
    just click, "Next Video."
  • 13:11 - 13:14
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
Maximizing Profit under Competition
Description:

A company in a competitive environment does not control prices. So the key to maximizing profit is choosing how much to produce. To do that, we need to factor in the costs involved in production. So what exactly are the costs? How do these costs influence how you maximize profit? And, remember, if you want to think like an economist, you must factor in opportunity cost!
In this video, we define profit, including how to calculate total revenue and total cost. We also go over fixed costs, variable costs, marginal revenue, and marginal cost
Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/profit-maximization-marginal-cost-marginal-revenue#QandA

Next video: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/profit-maximization-average-cost

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
13:16

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions