Return to Video

Solutions to Moral Hazard

  • 0:00 - 0:03
    ♪ [music] ♪
  • 0:14 - 0:15
    - [Tyler] In the previous video,
  • 0:15 - 0:18
    we discussed how
    asymmetric information
  • 0:18 - 0:19
    can lead to moral hazard,
  • 0:19 - 0:22
    which can lead
    to people being ripped off,
  • 0:22 - 0:25
    which in turn can lead
    to markets breaking down.
  • 0:25 - 0:28
    Now, there are two types
    of potential solutions
  • 0:28 - 0:30
    to moral hazard problems.
  • 0:30 - 0:33
    First, since the problem
    is asymmetric information,
  • 0:33 - 0:37
    you can try to make
    information less asymmetric.
  • 0:37 - 0:39
    If both parties
    have similar information,
  • 0:39 - 0:42
    then one party cannot
    so easily exploit the other.
  • 0:42 - 0:46
    Second, if you can't get rid
    of the information asymmetry,
  • 0:46 - 0:49
    you can try to reduce the incentive
    of the agent to exploit
  • 0:49 - 0:52
    his or her informational advantage.
  • 0:52 - 0:55
    One example
    that you're already familiar with
  • 0:55 - 0:57
    works along both
    of these dimensions:
  • 0:57 - 0:59
    user ratings.
  • 0:59 - 1:01
    You can get ratings
    for businesses at sites
  • 1:01 - 1:03
    such as Yelp and Angie's List,
  • 1:03 - 1:07
    and for products
    at places such as Amazon.com.
  • 1:07 - 1:11
    Reviews give you more information
    about a product or service,
  • 1:11 - 1:13
    and they help balance
    the information
  • 1:13 - 1:14
    between buyer and seller,
  • 1:14 - 1:18
    thereby mitigating issues
    of moral hazard.
  • 1:18 - 1:21
    Additionally, the existence
    of these review sites
  • 1:21 - 1:24
    changes the incentives
    for the sellers.
  • 1:24 - 1:26
    In our previous example
    of the auto mechanic
  • 1:26 - 1:30
    we sketched out how your incentive
    to get your car repaired
  • 1:30 - 1:32
    might conflict
    with the mechanic's incentive
  • 1:32 - 1:35
    to milk you for extra money.
  • 1:35 - 1:39
    However, the mechanic also
    has to think about her reputation,
  • 1:39 - 1:42
    which is what leads
    to future business.
  • 1:42 - 1:43
    Previously, you might have told,
  • 1:43 - 1:46
    well, just a few friends
    that you got ripped off.
  • 1:46 - 1:49
    Now, today, you can write
    an online review
  • 1:49 - 1:53
    and reach a much larger audience,
    maybe thousands of people.
  • 1:53 - 1:56
    A mechanic's online reputation
    is important to her success
  • 1:56 - 2:00
    and provides an incentive
    for her not to try to exploit
  • 2:00 - 2:02
    her informational advantage.
  • 2:02 - 2:06
    While review sites are great,
    the market is continually evolving,
  • 2:06 - 2:08
    and some sellers try to fight back
  • 2:08 - 2:12
    by faking or manipulating
    reviews or ratings.
  • 2:12 - 2:13
    There's some obvious examples,
  • 2:13 - 2:16
    like favorably reviewing
    your friend's book on Amazon
  • 2:16 - 2:18
    if your friend reviews yours.
  • 2:18 - 2:21
    But there are more
    subtle examples as well.
  • 2:21 - 2:24
    For instance, some universities
    invite lots of applicants,
  • 2:24 - 2:26
    knowing they will reject them,
  • 2:26 - 2:30
    just hoping to boost
    their rating for exclusivity.
  • 2:30 - 2:33
    Reviews are more trustworthy
    if they come from third parties
  • 2:33 - 2:36
    who do not have incentives
    to bias the review
  • 2:36 - 2:38
    one way or the other.
  • 2:38 - 2:40
    The magazine Consumer Reports,
    for example,
  • 2:40 - 2:43
    has a reputation
    for honest reporting
  • 2:43 - 2:46
    because it's a non-profit
    and it accepts no advertisements
  • 2:46 - 2:49
    and no funding
    from commercial sources.
  • 2:49 - 2:51
    But there's another problem --
  • 2:51 - 2:55
    it's hard to exclude people
    from produced information.
  • 2:55 - 2:58
    Information is also
    what we call nonrival --
  • 2:58 - 3:00
    nonexcludable and nonrival.
  • 3:00 - 3:03
    Do those property sound familiar?
  • 3:03 - 3:06
    Yes, information
    has the characteristics
  • 3:06 - 3:08
    of a public good.
  • 3:08 - 3:10
    Click to go back
    and review if you need.
  • 3:10 - 3:15
    It's hard for Consumer Reports
    to keep the information it provides
  • 3:15 - 3:18
    to only those people
    who buy the magazine.
  • 3:18 - 3:21
    If you hear that Consumer Reports
    says that brand X of television
  • 3:21 - 3:23
    is the very best,
  • 3:23 - 3:25
    well you might use that information
  • 3:25 - 3:28
    even if you didn't buy
    the magazine and pay for it.
  • 3:28 - 3:31
    In this case, we would say
    that you are free riding,
  • 3:31 - 3:33
    using the benefits
    of their research
  • 3:33 - 3:37
    and testing without contributing
    to paying the costs.
  • 3:37 - 3:42
    Free riding is a problem, however,
    not because it's unfair or unjust,
  • 3:42 - 3:44
    but because it means
    that information provision
  • 3:44 - 3:47
    may be under-provided
    in the first place.
  • 3:47 - 3:51
    As a result, there are fewer
    trustworthy third parties
  • 3:51 - 3:53
    reviewing products and services.
  • 3:53 - 3:56
    So, review sites help solve
    moral hazard issues
  • 3:56 - 4:00
    by both balancing the information
    between buyer and seller,
  • 4:00 - 4:03
    and reducing the incentives
    for the more informed party
  • 4:03 - 4:06
    to exploit
    an informational advantage.
  • 4:08 - 4:09
    There are other approaches
  • 4:09 - 4:12
    that work solely
    by modifying the incentives
  • 4:12 - 4:15
    of those people
    with the informational advantages.
  • 4:15 - 4:17
    Let's take two examples
  • 4:17 - 4:19
    that might seem
    completely different,
  • 4:19 - 4:21
    but are actually, conceptually,
    pretty similar:
  • 4:21 - 4:26
    house inspections,
    and second opinions from doctors.
  • 4:26 - 4:28
    When you buy a house,
    you typically get a home inspector
  • 4:28 - 4:32
    to check out the house
    and identify potential problems.
  • 4:32 - 4:34
    By law in many states,
  • 4:34 - 4:37
    these home inspectors
    cannot also sell services
  • 4:37 - 4:40
    to fix any problems
    they've identified.
  • 4:40 - 4:42
    This changes their incentives.
  • 4:42 - 4:44
    No longer do they have the incentive
  • 4:44 - 4:46
    to overstate
    potential problem issues
  • 4:46 - 4:48
    to inflate the bill.
  • 4:48 - 4:51
    Similarly, when you go to a doctor
    for a second opinion,
  • 4:51 - 4:54
    that doctor is simply
    diagnosing the problem,
  • 4:54 - 4:56
    but not doing the actual treatment.
  • 4:56 - 4:57
    Just like with the home inspector,
  • 4:57 - 5:01
    this eliminates the incentive
    to run up the bill.
  • 5:01 - 5:05
    Both of these examples
    split the diagnosis of the issue
  • 5:05 - 5:07
    from the actual work
    to address the problem.
  • 5:07 - 5:10
    So while the information
    is still asymmetric,
  • 5:10 - 5:14
    there is less of an incentive
    to exploit that asymmetry.
  • 5:14 - 5:17
    By the time you're ready
    to fix the issue,
  • 5:17 - 5:19
    this separate diagnosis by an expert
  • 5:19 - 5:22
    allows you to have
    much more information.
  • 5:22 - 5:26
    Maybe now, almost as much
    as the service provider in some ways.
  • 5:26 - 5:29
    This video has covered
    the various solutions
  • 5:29 - 5:30
    to moral hazard issues
  • 5:30 - 5:33
    in situations
    of asymmetric information.
  • 5:33 - 5:34
    In the next video,
  • 5:34 - 5:36
    we'll take up
    a different kind of response
  • 5:36 - 5:38
    to the asymmetric
    information problem,
  • 5:38 - 5:40
    namely signaling.
  • 5:40 - 5:42
    See you then.
  • 5:43 - 5:44
    - [Narrator] If you want
    to test yourself,
  • 5:44 - 5:46
    click "Practice Questions."
  • 5:46 - 5:50
    Or, if you're ready to move on,
    just click "Next Video."
  • 5:50 - 5:52
    ♪ [music] ♪
Title:
Solutions to Moral Hazard
Description:

What are some solutions to moral hazard? We could try to make information less asymmetric — meaning both parties have similar information, making it harder for one party to exploit the other. We could also try to reduce the incentive of the agent to exploit their information advantage. Online ratings and reviews on Yelp, Angie’s List, or Amazon, for instance, incorporate both of these solutions. The reviews give you more information about a product or service and close the information gap between buyers and sellers. In addition, sellers’ incentives change, as they now have to think about their reputation. They likely won’t want to exploit you if they know it will result in a negative online review.

What are some other approaches to modifying the incentives of those with an information advantage? One approach is to split the diagnosis of a problem from the actual work that needs to be done — for instance, home inspectors don’t fix the problems they identify during their inspection. Another approach is to alter the payment structure to change incentives. For instance, a lawyer is less likely to run up their hours when payment is contingent on winning your case as opposed to the number of hours they work on the case. Ethics also plays a role. Doctors swear to the Hippocratic Oath, which provides them an incentive to not exploit their information advantage. As you can see, there are many solutions to addressing moral hazard.

Microeconomics Course: http://mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics

Ask a question about the video: http://www.mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/solutions-moral-hazard-example#QandA

Next video: http://www.mruniversity.com/courses/principles-economics-microeconomics/signaling-economics

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
Marginal Revolution University
Project:
Micro
Duration:
05:55

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions