Return to Video

New thoughts on capital in the twenty-first century

  • 0:01 - 0:03
    It's very nice to be here tonight.
  • 0:03 - 0:07
    So I've been working on the history of income
  • 0:07 - 0:10
    and wealth distribution for the past 15 years,
  • 0:10 - 0:13
    and one of the interesting lessons
  • 0:13 - 0:16
    coming from this historical evidence
  • 0:16 - 0:18
    is indeed that, in the long run,
  • 0:18 - 0:21
    there is a tendency for
    the rate of return of capital
  • 0:21 - 0:24
    to exceed the economy's growth rate,
  • 0:24 - 0:27
    and this tends to lead to
    high concentration of wealth.
  • 0:27 - 0:28
    Not infinite concentration of wealth,
  • 0:28 - 0:31
    but the higher the gap between r and g,
  • 0:31 - 0:34
    the higher the level of inequality of wealth
  • 0:34 - 0:37
    towards which society tends to converge.
  • 0:37 - 0:41
    So this is a key force that
    I'm going to talk about today,
  • 0:41 - 0:43
    but let me say right away
  • 0:43 - 0:45
    that this is not the only important force
  • 0:45 - 0:48
    in the dynamics of income
    and wealth distribution,
  • 0:48 - 0:50
    and there are many other forces that play
  • 0:50 - 0:53
    an important role in the long-run dynamics
  • 0:53 - 0:54
    of income and wealth distribution.
  • 0:54 - 0:56
    Also there is a lot of data
  • 0:56 - 0:58
    that still needs to be collected.
  • 0:58 - 1:01
    We know a little bit more today
  • 1:01 - 1:03
    than we used to know,
    but we still know too little,
  • 1:03 - 1:06
    and certainly there are
    many different processes —
  • 1:06 - 1:08
    economic, social, political —
  • 1:08 - 1:10
    that need to be studied more.
  • 1:10 - 1:13
    And so I'm going to focus today on this simple force,
  • 1:13 - 1:15
    but that doesn't mean that other important forces
  • 1:15 - 1:16
    do not exist.
  • 1:16 - 1:18
    So most of the data I'm going to present
  • 1:18 - 1:21
    comes from this database
  • 1:21 - 1:22
    that's available online:
  • 1:22 - 1:23
    the World Top Incomes Database.
  • 1:23 - 1:25
    So this is the largest existing
  • 1:25 - 1:28
    historical database on inequality,
  • 1:28 - 1:29
    and this comes from the effort
  • 1:29 - 1:33
    of over 30 scholars from several dozen countries.
  • 1:33 - 1:36
    So let me show you a couple of facts
  • 1:36 - 1:37
    coming from this database,
  • 1:37 - 1:39
    and then we'll return to r bigger than g.
  • 1:39 - 1:42
    So fact number one is that there has been
  • 1:42 - 1:45
    a big reversal in the ordering of income inequality
  • 1:45 - 1:47
    between the United States and Europe
  • 1:47 - 1:48
    over the past century.
  • 1:48 - 1:52
    So back in 1900, 1910, income inequality was actually
  • 1:52 - 1:54
    much higher in Europe than in the United States,
  • 1:54 - 1:57
    whereas today, it is a lot higher in the United States.
  • 1:57 - 1:59
    So let me be very clear:
  • 1:59 - 2:02
    The main explanation for this is not r bigger than g.
  • 2:02 - 2:05
    It has more to do with changing supply and demand
  • 2:05 - 2:09
    for skill, the race between education and technology,
  • 2:09 - 2:12
    globalization, probably more unequal access
  • 2:12 - 2:14
    to skills in the U.S.,
  • 2:14 - 2:16
    where you have very good, very top universities
  • 2:16 - 2:19
    but where the bottom part of the educational system
  • 2:19 - 2:20
    is not as good,
  • 2:20 - 2:22
    so very unequal access to skills,
  • 2:22 - 2:24
    and also an unprecedented rise
  • 2:24 - 2:27
    of top managerial compensation of the United States,
  • 2:27 - 2:30
    which is difficult to account for
    just on the basis of education.
  • 2:30 - 2:32
    So there is more going on here,
  • 2:32 - 2:34
    but I'm not going to talk too much about this today,
  • 2:34 - 2:37
    because I want to focus on wealth inequality.
  • 2:37 - 2:40
    So let me just show you a very simple indicator
  • 2:40 - 2:42
    about the income inequality part.
  • 2:42 - 2:45
    So this is the share of total income
  • 2:45 - 2:46
    going to the top 10 percent.
  • 2:46 - 2:49
    So you can see that one century ago,
  • 2:49 - 2:52
    it was between 45 and 50 percent in Europe
  • 2:52 - 2:55
    and a little bit above 40 percent in the U.S.,
  • 2:55 - 2:57
    so there was more inequality in Europe.
  • 2:57 - 2:59
    Then there was a sharp decline
  • 2:59 - 3:02
    during the first half of the 20th century,
  • 3:02 - 3:04
    and in the recent decade, you can see that
  • 3:04 - 3:08
    the U.S. has become more unequal than Europe,
  • 3:08 - 3:10
    and this is the first fact I just talked about.
  • 3:10 - 3:14
    Now, the second fact is more about wealth inequality,
  • 3:14 - 3:17
    and here the central fact is that wealth inequality
  • 3:17 - 3:20
    is always a lot higher than income inequality,
  • 3:20 - 3:22
    and also that wealth inequality,
  • 3:22 - 3:25
    although it has also increased in recent decades,
  • 3:25 - 3:27
    is still less extreme today
  • 3:27 - 3:29
    than what it was a century ago,
  • 3:29 - 3:31
    although the total quantity of wealth
  • 3:31 - 3:33
    relative to income has now recovered
  • 3:33 - 3:35
    from the very large shocks
  • 3:35 - 3:37
    caused by World War I, the Great Depression,
  • 3:37 - 3:38
    World War II.
  • 3:38 - 3:40
    So let me show you two graphs
  • 3:40 - 3:43
    illustrating fact number two and fact number three.
  • 3:43 - 3:47
    So first, if you look at the level of wealth inequality,
  • 3:47 - 3:51
    this is the share of total wealth
  • 3:51 - 3:53
    going to the top 10 percent of wealth holders,
  • 3:53 - 3:56
    so you can see the same kind of reversal
  • 3:56 - 3:58
    between the U.S. and Europe that we had before
  • 3:58 - 4:00
    for income inequality.
  • 4:00 - 4:04
    So wealth concentration was higher
  • 4:04 - 4:06
    in Europe than in the U.S. a century ago,
  • 4:06 - 4:08
    and now it is the opposite.
  • 4:08 - 4:10
    But you can also show two things:
  • 4:10 - 4:13
    First, the general level of wealth inequality
  • 4:13 - 4:16
    is always higher than income inequality.
  • 4:16 - 4:18
    So remember, for income inequality,
  • 4:18 - 4:21
    the share going to the top 10 percent
  • 4:21 - 4:25
    was between 30 and 50 percent of total income,
  • 4:25 - 4:28
    whereas for wealth, the share is always
  • 4:28 - 4:30
    between 60 and 90 percent.
  • 4:30 - 4:31
    Okay, so that's fact number one,
  • 4:31 - 4:33
    and that's very important for what follows.
  • 4:33 - 4:35
    Wealth concentration is always
  • 4:35 - 4:37
    a lot higher than income concentration.
  • 4:37 - 4:40
    Fact number two is that the rise
  • 4:40 - 4:43
    in wealth inequality in recent decades
  • 4:43 - 4:47
    is still not enough to get us back to 1910.
  • 4:47 - 4:49
    So the big difference today,
  • 4:49 - 4:51
    wealth inequality is still very large,
  • 4:51 - 4:54
    with 60, 70 percent of total wealth for the top 10,
  • 4:54 - 4:56
    but the good news is that it's actually
  • 4:56 - 4:58
    better than one century ago,
  • 4:58 - 5:01
    where you had 90 percent in
    Europe going to the top 10.
  • 5:01 - 5:03
    So today what you have
  • 5:03 - 5:05
    is what I call the middle 40 percent,
  • 5:05 - 5:07
    the people who are not in the top 10
  • 5:07 - 5:09
    and who are not in the bottom 50,
  • 5:09 - 5:11
    and what you can view as the wealth middle class
  • 5:11 - 5:15
    that owns 20 to 30 percent
  • 5:15 - 5:16
    of total wealth, national wealth,
  • 5:16 - 5:20
    whereas they used to be poor, a century ago,
  • 5:20 - 5:22
    when there was basically no wealth middle class.
  • 5:22 - 5:24
    So this is an important change,
  • 5:24 - 5:29
    and it's interesting to see that wealth inequality
  • 5:29 - 5:32
    has not fully recovered to pre-World War I levels,
  • 5:32 - 5:35
    although the total quantity of wealth has recovered.
  • 5:35 - 5:37
    Okay? So this is the total value
  • 5:37 - 5:40
    of wealth relative to income,
  • 5:40 - 5:42
    and you can see that in particular in Europe,
  • 5:42 - 5:45
    we are almost back to the pre-World War I level.
  • 5:45 - 5:47
    So there are really two
  • 5:47 - 5:50
    different parts of the story here.
  • 5:50 - 5:51
    One has to do with
  • 5:51 - 5:53
    the total quantity of wealth that we accumulate,
  • 5:53 - 5:55
    and there is nothing bad per se, of course,
  • 5:55 - 5:57
    in accumulating a lot of wealth,
  • 5:57 - 6:00
    and in particular if it is more diffuse
  • 6:00 - 6:01
    and less concentrated.
  • 6:01 - 6:04
    So what we really want to focus on
  • 6:04 - 6:06
    is the long-run evolution of wealth inequality,
  • 6:06 - 6:09
    and what's going to happen in the future.
  • 6:09 - 6:11
    How can we account for the fact that
  • 6:11 - 6:14
    until World War I, wealth inequality was so high
  • 6:14 - 6:17
    and, if anything, was rising to even higher levels,
  • 6:17 - 6:21
    and how can we think about the future?
  • 6:21 - 6:25
    So let me come to some of the explanations
  • 6:25 - 6:27
    and speculations about the future.
  • 6:27 - 6:28
    Let me first say that
  • 6:28 - 6:30
    probably the best model to explain
  • 6:30 - 6:32
    why wealth is so much
  • 6:32 - 6:35
    more concentrated than income
  • 6:35 - 6:38
    is a dynamic, dynastic model
  • 6:38 - 6:40
    where individuals have a long horizon
  • 6:40 - 6:43
    and accumulate wealth for all sorts of reasons.
  • 6:43 - 6:46
    If people were accumulating wealth
  • 6:46 - 6:48
    only for life cycle reasons,
  • 6:48 - 6:50
    you know, to be able to consume
  • 6:50 - 6:51
    when they are old,
  • 6:51 - 6:54
    then the level of wealth inequality
  • 6:54 - 6:56
    should be more or less in line
  • 6:56 - 6:58
    with the level of income inequality.
  • 6:58 - 7:00
    But it will be very difficult to explain
  • 7:00 - 7:02
    why you have so much more wealth inequality
  • 7:02 - 7:03
    than income inequality
  • 7:03 - 7:05
    with a pure life cycle model,
  • 7:05 - 7:07
    so you need a story
  • 7:07 - 7:08
    where people also care
  • 7:08 - 7:11
    about wealth accumulation for other reasons.
  • 7:11 - 7:13
    So typically, they want to transmit
  • 7:13 - 7:16
    wealth to the next generation, to their children,
  • 7:16 - 7:18
    or sometimes they want to accumulate wealth
  • 7:18 - 7:21
    because of the prestige, the
    power that goes with wealth.
  • 7:21 - 7:22
    So there must be other reasons
  • 7:22 - 7:24
    for accumulating wealth than just life cycle
  • 7:24 - 7:27
    to explain what we see in the data.
  • 7:27 - 7:30
    Now, in a large class of dynamic models
  • 7:30 - 7:32
    of wealth accumulation
  • 7:32 - 7:36
    with such dynastic motive for accumulating wealth,
  • 7:36 - 7:39
    you will have all sorts of random,
  • 7:39 - 7:40
    multiplicative shocks.
  • 7:40 - 7:42
    So for instance, some families
  • 7:42 - 7:43
    have a very large number of children,
  • 7:43 - 7:45
    so the wealth will be divided.
  • 7:45 - 7:47
    Some families have fewer children.
  • 7:47 - 7:49
    You also have shocks to rates of return.
  • 7:49 - 7:51
    Some families make huge capital gains.
  • 7:51 - 7:53
    Some made bad investments.
  • 7:53 - 7:55
    So you will always have some mobility
  • 7:55 - 7:57
    in the wealth process.
  • 7:57 - 7:59
    Some people will move up,
    some people will move down.
  • 7:59 - 8:01
    The important point is that,
  • 8:01 - 8:02
    in any such model,
  • 8:02 - 8:05
    for a given variance of such shocks,
  • 8:05 - 8:07
    the equilibrium level of wealth inequality
  • 8:07 - 8:11
    will be a steeply rising function of r minus g.
  • 8:11 - 8:14
    And intuitively, the reason why the difference
  • 8:14 - 8:16
    between the rate of return to wealth
  • 8:16 - 8:18
    and the growth rate is important
  • 8:18 - 8:20
    is that initial wealth inequalities
  • 8:20 - 8:23
    will be amplified at a faster pace
  • 8:23 - 8:25
    with a bigger r minus g.
  • 8:25 - 8:26
    So take a simple example,
  • 8:26 - 8:30
    with r equals five percent and g equals one percent,
  • 8:30 - 8:32
    wealth holders only need to reinvest
  • 8:32 - 8:35
    one fifth of their capital income to ensure
  • 8:35 - 8:37
    that their wealth rises as fast
  • 8:37 - 8:39
    as the size of the economy.
  • 8:39 - 8:41
    So this makes it easier
  • 8:41 - 8:42
    to build and perpetuate large fortunes
  • 8:42 - 8:44
    because you can consume four fifths,
  • 8:44 - 8:46
    assuming zero tax,
  • 8:46 - 8:48
    and you can just reinvest one fifth.
  • 8:48 - 8:50
    So of course some families
    will consume more than that,
  • 8:50 - 8:52
    some will consume less, so there will be
  • 8:52 - 8:54
    some mobility in the distribution,
  • 8:54 - 8:57
    but on average, they only need to reinvest one fifth,
  • 8:57 - 9:00
    so this allows high wealth inequalities to be sustained.
  • 9:00 - 9:03
    Now, you should not be surprised
  • 9:03 - 9:07
    by the statement that r can be bigger than g forever,
  • 9:07 - 9:08
    because, in fact, this is what happened
  • 9:08 - 9:10
    during most of the history of mankind.
  • 9:10 - 9:14
    And this was in a way very obvious to everybody
  • 9:14 - 9:15
    for a simple reason, which is that growth
  • 9:15 - 9:18
    was close to zero percent
  • 9:18 - 9:19
    during most of the history of mankind.
  • 9:19 - 9:23
    Growth was maybe 0.1, 0.2, 0.3 percent,
  • 9:23 - 9:25
    but very slow growth of population
  • 9:25 - 9:27
    and output per capita,
  • 9:27 - 9:29
    whereas the rate of return on capital
  • 9:29 - 9:30
    of course was not zero percent.
  • 9:30 - 9:32
    It was, for land assets, which was
  • 9:32 - 9:34
    the traditional form
  • 9:34 - 9:37
    of assets in preindustrial societies,
  • 9:37 - 9:38
    it was typically five percent.
  • 9:38 - 9:42
    Any reader of Jane Austen would know that.
  • 9:42 - 9:45
    If you want an annual income of 1,000 pounds,
  • 9:45 - 9:47
    you should have a capital value
  • 9:47 - 9:49
    of 20,000 pounds so that
  • 9:49 - 9:51
    five percent of 20,000 is 1,000.
  • 9:51 - 9:53
    And in a way, this was
  • 9:53 - 9:55
    the very foundation of society,
  • 9:55 - 9:58
    because r bigger than g
  • 9:58 - 10:02
    was what allowed holders of wealth and assets
  • 10:02 - 10:05
    to live off their capital income
  • 10:05 - 10:07
    and to do something else in life
  • 10:07 - 10:11
    than just to care about their own survival.
  • 10:11 - 10:13
    Now, one important conclusion
  • 10:13 - 10:15
    of my historical research is that
  • 10:15 - 10:18
    modern industrial growth did not change
  • 10:18 - 10:20
    this basic fact as much as one might have expected.
  • 10:20 - 10:22
    Of course, the growth rate
  • 10:22 - 10:24
    following the Industrial Revolution
  • 10:24 - 10:28
    rose, typically from zero to one to two percent,
  • 10:28 - 10:30
    but at the same time, the rate of return
  • 10:30 - 10:32
    to capital also rose
  • 10:32 - 10:34
    so that the gap between the two
  • 10:34 - 10:36
    did not really change.
  • 10:36 - 10:38
    So during the 20th century,
  • 10:38 - 10:41
    you had a very unique combination of events.
  • 10:41 - 10:43
    First, a very low rate of return
  • 10:43 - 10:46
    due to the 1914 and 1945 war shocks,
  • 10:46 - 10:48
    destruction of wealth, inflation,
  • 10:48 - 10:50
    bankruptcy during the Great Depression,
  • 10:50 - 10:52
    and all of this reduced
  • 10:52 - 10:53
    the private rate of return to wealth
  • 10:53 - 10:55
    to unusually low levels
  • 10:55 - 10:57
    between 1914 and 1945.
  • 10:57 - 10:59
    And then, in the postwar period,
  • 10:59 - 11:03
    you had unusually high growth rate,
  • 11:03 - 11:05
    partly due to the reconstruction.
  • 11:05 - 11:07
    You know, in Germany, in France, in Japan,
  • 11:07 - 11:08
    you had five percent growth rate
  • 11:08 - 11:12
    between 1950 and 1980
  • 11:12 - 11:13
    largely due to reconstruction,
  • 11:13 - 11:16
    and also due to very large demographic growth,
  • 11:16 - 11:18
    the Baby Boom Cohort effect.
  • 11:18 - 11:20
    Now, apparently that's not going to last for very long,
  • 11:20 - 11:22
    or at least the population growth
  • 11:22 - 11:25
    is supposed to decline in the future,
  • 11:25 - 11:28
    and the best projections we have is that
  • 11:28 - 11:30
    the long-run growth is going to be closer
  • 11:30 - 11:31
    to one to two percent
  • 11:31 - 11:33
    rather than four to five percent.
  • 11:33 - 11:36
    So if you look at this,
  • 11:36 - 11:38
    these are the best estimates we have
  • 11:38 - 11:40
    of world GDP growth
  • 11:40 - 11:42
    and rate of return on capital,
  • 11:42 - 11:44
    average rates of return on capital,
  • 11:44 - 11:45
    so you can see that during most
  • 11:45 - 11:47
    of the history of mankind,
  • 11:47 - 11:49
    the growth rate was very small,
  • 11:49 - 11:50
    much lower than the rate of return,
  • 11:50 - 11:53
    and then during the 20th century,
  • 11:53 - 11:55
    it is really the population growth,
  • 11:55 - 11:57
    very high in the postwar period,
  • 11:57 - 11:59
    and the reconstruction process
  • 11:59 - 12:00
    that brought growth
  • 12:00 - 12:03
    to a smaller gap with the rate of return.
  • 12:03 - 12:07
    Here I use the United Nations population projections,
  • 12:07 - 12:09
    so of course they are uncertain.
  • 12:09 - 12:11
    It could be that we all start
  • 12:11 - 12:13
    having a lot of children in the future,
  • 12:13 - 12:16
    and the growth rates are going to be higher,
  • 12:16 - 12:17
    but from now on,
  • 12:17 - 12:20
    these are the best projections we have,
  • 12:20 - 12:22
    and this will make global growth
  • 12:22 - 12:24
    decline and the gap between
  • 12:24 - 12:26
    the rate of return go up.
  • 12:26 - 12:29
    Now, the other unusual event
  • 12:29 - 12:31
    during the 20th century
  • 12:31 - 12:32
    was, as I said,
  • 12:32 - 12:35
    destruction, taxation of capital,
  • 12:35 - 12:37
    so this is the pre-tax rate of return.
  • 12:37 - 12:40
    This is the after-tax rate of return,
  • 12:40 - 12:42
    and after destruction,
  • 12:42 - 12:44
    and this is what brought
  • 12:44 - 12:45
    the average rate of return
  • 12:45 - 12:47
    after tax, after destruction,
  • 12:47 - 12:50
    below the growth rate during a long time period.
  • 12:50 - 12:51
    But without the destruction,
  • 12:51 - 12:54
    without the taxation, this
    would not have happened.
  • 12:54 - 12:57
    So let me say that the balance between
  • 12:57 - 12:59
    returns on capital and growth
  • 12:59 - 13:01
    depends on many different factors
  • 13:01 - 13:03
    that are very difficult to predict:
  • 13:03 - 13:05
    technology and the development
  • 13:05 - 13:08
    of capital-intensive techniques.
  • 13:08 - 13:11
    So right now, the most capital-intensive sectors
  • 13:11 - 13:14
    in the economy are the real estate sector, housing,
  • 13:14 - 13:17
    the energy sector, but it could be in the future
  • 13:17 - 13:21
    that we have a lot more robots in a number of sectors
  • 13:21 - 13:23
    and that this would be a bigger share
  • 13:23 - 13:25
    of the total capital stock that it is today.
  • 13:25 - 13:27
    Well, we are very far from this,
  • 13:27 - 13:28
    and from now, what's going on
  • 13:28 - 13:30
    in the real estate sector, the energy sector,
  • 13:30 - 13:32
    is much more important for the total capital stock
  • 13:32 - 13:34
    and capital share.
  • 13:34 - 13:36
    The other important issue
  • 13:36 - 13:38
    is that there are scale effects
    in portfolio management,
  • 13:38 - 13:40
    together with financial complexity,
  • 13:40 - 13:42
    financial deregulation,
  • 13:42 - 13:44
    that make it easier to get higher rates of return
  • 13:44 - 13:46
    for a large portfolio,
  • 13:46 - 13:49
    and this seems to be particularly strong
  • 13:49 - 13:51
    for billionaires, large capital endowments.
  • 13:51 - 13:53
    Just to give you one example,
  • 13:53 - 13:56
    this comes from the Forbes billionaire rankings
  • 13:56 - 14:00
    over the 1987-2013 period,
  • 14:00 - 14:02
    and you can see the very top wealth holders
  • 14:02 - 14:05
    have been going up at six, seven percent per year
  • 14:05 - 14:08
    in real terms above inflation,
  • 14:08 - 14:10
    whereas average income in the world,
  • 14:10 - 14:12
    average wealth in the world,
  • 14:12 - 14:15
    have increased at only two percent per year.
  • 14:15 - 14:17
    And you find the same
  • 14:17 - 14:18
    for large university endowments —
  • 14:18 - 14:20
    the bigger the initial endowments,
  • 14:20 - 14:22
    the bigger the rate of return.
  • 14:22 - 14:24
    Now, what could be done?
  • 14:24 - 14:26
    The first thing is that I think we need
  • 14:26 - 14:28
    more financial transparency.
  • 14:28 - 14:32
    We know too little about global wealth dynamics,
  • 14:32 - 14:34
    so we need international transmission
  • 14:34 - 14:35
    of bank information.
  • 14:35 - 14:38
    We need a global registry of financial assets,
  • 14:38 - 14:41
    more coordination on wealth taxation,
  • 14:41 - 14:44
    and even wealth tax with a small tax rate
  • 14:44 - 14:46
    will be a way to produce information
  • 14:46 - 14:49
    so that then we can adapt our policies
  • 14:49 - 14:51
    to whatever we observe.
  • 14:51 - 14:52
    And to some extent, the fight
  • 14:52 - 14:54
    against tax havens
  • 14:54 - 14:56
    and automatic transmission of information
  • 14:56 - 14:57
    is pushing us in this direction.
  • 14:57 - 15:00
    Now, there are other ways to redistribute wealth,
  • 15:00 - 15:03
    which it can be tempting to use.
  • 15:03 - 15:04
    Inflation:
  • 15:04 - 15:06
    it's much easier to print money
  • 15:06 - 15:08
    than to write a tax code, so that's very tempting,
  • 15:08 - 15:10
    but sometimes you don't know
    what you do with the money.
  • 15:10 - 15:12
    This is a problem.
  • 15:12 - 15:14
    Expropriation is very tempting.
  • 15:14 - 15:16
    Just when you feel some people get too wealthy,
  • 15:16 - 15:17
    you just expropriate them.
  • 15:17 - 15:19
    But this is not a very efficient way
  • 15:19 - 15:22
    to organize a regulation of wealth dynamics.
  • 15:22 - 15:24
    So war is an even less efficient way,
  • 15:24 - 15:27
    so I tend to prefer progressive taxation,
  • 15:27 - 15:29
    but of course, history — (Laughter) —
  • 15:29 - 15:31
    history will invent its own best ways,
  • 15:31 - 15:33
    and it will probably involve
  • 15:33 - 15:34
    a combination of all of these.
  • 15:34 - 15:36
    Thank you.
  • 15:36 - 15:38
    (Applause)
  • 15:38 - 15:44
    Bruno Giussani: Thomas Piketty. Thank you.
  • 15:44 - 15:46
    Thomas, I want to ask you two or three questions,
  • 15:46 - 15:50
    because it's impressive how you're
    in command of your data, of course,
  • 15:50 - 15:53
    but basically what you suggest is
  • 15:53 - 15:55
    growing wealth concentration is kind of
  • 15:55 - 15:57
    a natural tendency of capitalism,
  • 15:57 - 16:00
    and if we leave it to its own devices,
  • 16:00 - 16:03
    it may threaten the system itself,
  • 16:03 - 16:04
    so you're suggesting that we need to act
  • 16:04 - 16:07
    to implement policies that redistribute wealth,
  • 16:07 - 16:09
    including the ones we just saw:
  • 16:09 - 16:11
    progressive taxation, etc.
  • 16:11 - 16:13
    In the current political context,
  • 16:13 - 16:15
    how realistic are those?
  • 16:15 - 16:17
    How likely do you think that it is
  • 16:17 - 16:18
    that they will be implemented?
  • 16:18 - 16:19
    Thomas Piketty: Well, you know, I think
  • 16:19 - 16:21
    if you look back through time,
  • 16:21 - 16:24
    the history of income, wealth and taxation
  • 16:24 - 16:26
    is full of surprise.
  • 16:26 - 16:28
    So I am not terribly impressed
  • 16:28 - 16:30
    by those who know in advance
  • 16:30 - 16:31
    what will or will not happen.
  • 16:31 - 16:33
    I think one century ago,
  • 16:33 - 16:35
    many people would have said
  • 16:35 - 16:37
    that progressive income taxation would never happen
  • 16:37 - 16:38
    and then it happened.
  • 16:38 - 16:40
    And even five years ago,
  • 16:40 - 16:43
    many people would have said that bank secrecy
  • 16:43 - 16:45
    will be with us forever in Switzerland,
  • 16:45 - 16:46
    that Switzerland was too powerful
  • 16:46 - 16:48
    for the rest of the world,
  • 16:48 - 16:51
    and then suddenly it took a few U.S. sanctions
  • 16:51 - 16:53
    against Swiss banks for a big change to happen,
  • 16:53 - 16:55
    and now we are moving toward
  • 16:55 - 16:57
    more financial transparency.
  • 16:57 - 17:01
    So I think it's not that difficult
  • 17:01 - 17:04
    to better coordinate politically.
  • 17:04 - 17:06
    We are going to have a treaty
  • 17:06 - 17:09
    with half of the world GDP around the table
  • 17:09 - 17:11
    with the U.S. and the European Union,
  • 17:11 - 17:13
    so if half of the world GDP is not enough
  • 17:13 - 17:16
    to make progress on financial transparency
  • 17:16 - 17:20
    and minimal tax for multinational corporate profits,
  • 17:20 - 17:21
    what does it take?
  • 17:21 - 17:25
    So I think these are not technical difficulties.
  • 17:25 - 17:27
    I think we can make progress
  • 17:27 - 17:29
    if we have a more pragmatic
    approach to these questions
  • 17:29 - 17:31
    and we have the proper sanctions
  • 17:31 - 17:34
    on those who benefit from financial opacity.
  • 17:34 - 17:36
    BG: One of the arguments
  • 17:36 - 17:37
    against your point of view
  • 17:37 - 17:39
    is that economic inequality
  • 17:39 - 17:42
    is not only a feature of capitalism
    but is actually one of its engines.
  • 17:42 - 17:45
    So we take measures to lower inequality,
  • 17:45 - 17:48
    and at the same time we lower growth, potentially.
  • 17:48 - 17:49
    What do you answer to that?
  • 17:49 - 17:51
    TP: Yeah, I think inequality
  • 17:51 - 17:53
    is not a problem per se.
  • 17:53 - 17:55
    I think inequality up to a point
  • 17:55 - 17:58
    can actually be useful for innovation and growth.
  • 17:58 - 18:00
    The problem is, it's a question of degree.
  • 18:00 - 18:02
    When inequality gets too extreme,
  • 18:02 - 18:05
    then it becomes useless for growth
  • 18:05 - 18:07
    and it can even become bad
  • 18:07 - 18:10
    because it tends to lead to high perpetuation
  • 18:10 - 18:11
    of inequality over time
  • 18:11 - 18:13
    and low mobility.
  • 18:13 - 18:16
    And for instance, the kind of wealth concentrations
  • 18:16 - 18:19
    that we had in the 19th century
  • 18:19 - 18:21
    and pretty much until World War I
  • 18:21 - 18:23
    in every European country
  • 18:23 - 18:25
    was, I think, not useful for growth.
  • 18:25 - 18:27
    This was destroyed by a combination
  • 18:27 - 18:30
    of tragic events and policy changes,
  • 18:30 - 18:32
    and this did not prevent growth from happening.
  • 18:32 - 18:35
    And also, extreme inequality can be bad
  • 18:35 - 18:37
    for our democratic institutions
  • 18:37 - 18:40
    if it creates very unequal access to political voice,
  • 18:40 - 18:42
    and the influence of private money
  • 18:42 - 18:44
    in U.S. politics, I think,
  • 18:44 - 18:46
    is a matter of concern right now.
  • 18:46 - 18:49
    So we don't want to return to that kind of extreme,
  • 18:49 - 18:51
    pre-World War I inequality.
  • 18:51 - 18:55
    Having a decent share of the national wealth
  • 18:55 - 18:58
    for the middle class is not bad for growth.
  • 18:58 - 19:00
    It is actually useful
  • 19:00 - 19:03
    both for equity and efficiency reasons.
  • 19:03 - 19:05
    BG: I said at the beginning
  • 19:05 - 19:07
    that your book has been criticized.
  • 19:07 - 19:08
    Some of your data has been criticized.
  • 19:08 - 19:10
    Some of your choice of data sets has been criticized.
  • 19:10 - 19:12
    You have been accused of cherry-picking data
  • 19:12 - 19:15
    to make your case. What do you answer to that?
  • 19:15 - 19:17
    TP: Well, I answer that I am very happy
  • 19:17 - 19:19
    that this book is stimulating debate.
  • 19:19 - 19:22
    This is part of what it is intended for.
  • 19:22 - 19:25
    Look, the reason why I put all the data online
  • 19:25 - 19:27
    with all of the detailed computation
  • 19:27 - 19:29
    is so that we can have
    an open and transparent
  • 19:29 - 19:31
    debate about this.
  • 19:31 - 19:33
    So I have responded point by point
  • 19:33 - 19:35
    to every concern.
  • 19:35 - 19:38
    Let me say that if I was to rewrite the book today,
  • 19:38 - 19:39
    I would actually conclude
  • 19:39 - 19:41
    that the rise in wealth inequality,
  • 19:41 - 19:43
    particularly in the United States,
  • 19:43 - 19:46
    has been actually higher
    than what I report in my book.
  • 19:46 - 19:49
    There is a recent study by Saez and Zucman
  • 19:49 - 19:51
    showing, with new data
  • 19:51 - 19:52
    which I didn't have at the time of the book,
  • 19:52 - 19:55
    that wealth concentration in the U.S. has risen
  • 19:55 - 19:57
    even more than what I report.
  • 19:57 - 19:59
    And there will be other data in the future.
  • 19:59 - 20:01
    Some of it will go in different directions.
  • 20:01 - 20:05
    Look, we put online almost every week
  • 20:05 - 20:08
    new, updated series on the
    World Top Income Database
  • 20:08 - 20:10
    and we will keep doing so in the future,
  • 20:10 - 20:12
    in particular in emerging countries,
  • 20:12 - 20:15
    and I welcome all of those who want to contribute
  • 20:15 - 20:17
    to this data collection process.
  • 20:17 - 20:20
    In fact, I certainly agree
  • 20:20 - 20:22
    that there is not enough
  • 20:22 - 20:24
    transparency about wealth dynamics,
  • 20:24 - 20:26
    and a good way to have better data
  • 20:26 - 20:28
    would be to have a wealth tax
  • 20:28 - 20:29
    with a small tax rate to begin with
  • 20:29 - 20:31
    so that we can all agree
  • 20:31 - 20:33
    about this important evolution
  • 20:33 - 20:36
    and adapt our policies to whatever we observe.
  • 20:36 - 20:38
    So taxation is a source of knowledge,
  • 20:38 - 20:41
    and that's what we need the most right now.
  • 20:41 - 20:43
    BG: Thomas Piketty, merci beaucoup.
  • 20:43 - 20:47
    Thank you.
    TP: Thank you. (Applause)
Title:
New thoughts on capital in the twenty-first century
Speaker:
Thomas Piketty
Description:

French economist Thomas Piketty caused a sensation in early 2014 with his book on a simple, brutal formula explaining economic inequality: r > g (meaning that return on capital is generally higher than economic growth). Here, he talks through the massive data set that led him to conclude: Economic inequality is not new, but it is getting worse, with radical possible impacts.

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
closed TED
Project:
TEDTalks
Duration:
21:00

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions