WEBVTT 00:00:00.000 --> 00:00:13.149 33c3 pre-roll music 00:00:13.159 --> 00:00:15.269 Herald: Err ... 00:00:15.289 --> 00:00:17.820 H: ... a talk would be good, right? 00:00:18.290 --> 00:00:24.529 applause 00:00:26.169 --> 00:00:27.330 Do you want to give a talk? 00:00:27.340 --> 00:00:31.390 Toni: Aah, it’s a little early but I’ll try. 00:00:31.390 --> 00:00:36.360 Herald: Okay, guys, well, I found someone who’s willing to give a talk! 00:00:36.430 --> 00:00:41.820 laughter and applause 00:00:42.430 --> 00:00:47.010 That is most excellent. So, if you ever asked yourself, 00:00:47.770 --> 00:00:53.120 I’ve got this big regime and I’m rolling out internet censorship, 00:00:53.120 --> 00:00:56.449 what does my economy do? 00:00:56.449 --> 00:00:59.449 There are people in here asking that question, right? 00:00:59.449 --> 00:01:02.750 There’s always someone at Congress who’s asking some question. 00:01:02.760 --> 00:01:09.310 Well, you came to the right place, and as part of her PhD thesis work 00:01:09.320 --> 00:01:15.030 Toni is going answer that question, hopefully, to a satisfactory point. 00:01:15.030 --> 00:01:17.570 Please give a warm round of applause! applause 00:01:17.580 --> 00:01:24.180 Toni! ongoing applause 00:01:24.180 --> 00:01:27.520 Toni: Okay, thanks everyone for being here, I hope you can all hear me 00:01:27.540 --> 00:01:32.590 correctly. And I’m glad to be here and to be presenting 00:01:32.590 --> 00:01:36.109 some part of my thesis to day. Now, this is ongoing work 00:01:36.109 --> 00:01:39.520 so I’m really grateful for any kind of feedback that you guys would have 00:01:39.520 --> 00:01:43.300 and I’m really only presenting this as kind of a first try, 00:01:43.300 --> 00:01:46.840 because when I looked at the topic of internet censorship 00:01:46.840 --> 00:01:51.549 and what that could mean for an economy, I really didn’t find anything academic 00:01:51.549 --> 00:01:56.280 and I was quite surprised: it seemed like a very obvious question to me, 00:01:56.280 --> 00:02:00.979 because I was looking mostly at China at the beginning. 00:02:00.979 --> 00:02:04.740 And I read a lot of newspaper articles and I talked to a lot of businessmen 00:02:04.740 --> 00:02:08.060 who told me: “Well, doing business in China is very difficult” 00:02:08.060 --> 00:02:11.020 and I think China is really holding itself back by having 00:02:11.020 --> 00:02:15.400 this big censorship thing going. 00:02:15.400 --> 00:02:20.670 But no one really looked into how it is holding itself back 00:02:20.670 --> 00:02:23.860 or if it is even holding itself back. 00:02:23.860 --> 00:02:26.940 So there is really very, very little research. 00:02:26.940 --> 00:02:32.050 And we don’t even have an agreement among economists or business studies people 00:02:32.050 --> 00:02:36.420 about what impact the internet has on the economy. So if you want to ask: 00:02:36.420 --> 00:02:39.890 “So what does internet censorship do to an economy?” it seems pretty obvious 00:02:39.890 --> 00:02:44.830 to first ask: “What does the internet do to an economy?” and we don’t even know that. 00:02:44.830 --> 00:02:47.990 That was quite surprising to me and I’m going to be talking about the reasons 00:02:47.990 --> 00:02:53.310 for that a little bit later on. But in general, I was thinking of a research 00:02:53.310 --> 00:02:58.460 question to ask which for me is: “Does internet censorship reduce economic welfare?” 00:02:58.460 --> 00:03:03.030 Now, not all of you are economists, so some of you might think of welfare 00:03:03.030 --> 00:03:08.200 more as the transfer payments that a state gives to its poorer people. 00:03:08.200 --> 00:03:12.800 But for economists, economic welfare is defined as the consumer 00:03:12.800 --> 00:03:18.130 and producer surplus. So basically, the difference between what something costs 00:03:18.130 --> 00:03:21.760 and what you can sell it for is the producer surplus. 00:03:21.760 --> 00:03:25.160 The difference between what you would be willing to pay 00:03:25.160 --> 00:03:28.250 and what you’re actually paying is your consumer surplus. 00:03:28.250 --> 00:03:32.360 Now let’s assume I have a laptop and I bought this. 00:03:32.360 --> 00:03:35.910 And I would have been willing to pay € 1500 for this laptop because 00:03:35.910 --> 00:03:39.860 I think it’s a very good product, it’s by Lenovo that makes good laptops. 00:03:39.860 --> 00:03:44.260 But actually I got it for like €800 or €900. That would mean 00:03:44.260 --> 00:03:49.410 my personal consumer surplus is something like €600 or €700. 00:03:49.410 --> 00:03:52.910 And if we add up everyone’s individual consumer surplus 00:03:52.910 --> 00:03:58.840 we get the economic welfare surplus. 00:03:58.840 --> 00:04:02.660 So first, I was trying to figure out what does the internet mean 00:04:02.660 --> 00:04:07.630 for the economy. And I’ve said that there is really no good agreement on that. 00:04:07.630 --> 00:04:12.330 Now, a very crude measure that I found is how much does "the Internet economy" 00:04:12.330 --> 00:04:17.780 contribute to GDP? Now, what is "the internet economy"? 00:04:17.780 --> 00:04:22.280 It wasn’t very clear in the research that I’ve read. It seems to be sort of 00:04:22.280 --> 00:04:27.620 online retail, and possibly some other internet-enabled services? 00:04:27.620 --> 00:04:31.130 Possibly but not necessarily internet advertisement revenue 00:04:31.130 --> 00:04:36.140 is reflected in this. But because it was BCG, which is a big consulting agency 00:04:36.140 --> 00:04:40.870 that basically published this research they weren’t very diligent about 00:04:40.870 --> 00:04:45.670 their methods, basically. So we can see, well it seems that the UK 00:04:45.670 --> 00:04:49.720 has a pretty big part of internet economy as part of GDP. 00:04:49.720 --> 00:04:53.760 That’s probably mostly because of online retail which is bigger in the UK 00:04:53.760 --> 00:04:57.310 than in most other countries we look at. And we see that there is 00:04:57.310 --> 00:05:01.680 a small difference between developed and developing market averages 00:05:01.680 --> 00:05:06.980 when looking only at the G20 countries. But this seems like a very 00:05:06.980 --> 00:05:10.330 dissatisfactory answer because first of all, I don’t know the methods, 00:05:10.330 --> 00:05:12.870 so I can’t really say whether this is actually good. 00:05:12.870 --> 00:05:16.350 And secondly, GDP is actually not a good measure 00:05:16.350 --> 00:05:20.490 for what we are trying to measure because a lot of the stuff that the internet creates, 00:05:20.490 --> 00:05:25.830 a lot of the value the internet creates isn’t captured by GDP at all. 00:05:25.830 --> 00:05:30.310 One example is free online courses. Most of the online courses you can take 00:05:30.310 --> 00:05:34.290 on the web are actually free. And most of them are not ad-enabled. 00:05:34.290 --> 00:05:40.690 So most of them don’t really have advertisements in the general sense. 00:05:40.690 --> 00:05:46.380 So classical economics basically says: “Well, they don’t really create any value.” 00:05:46.380 --> 00:05:48.650 But if you’ve ever taken one of these online courses, 00:05:48.650 --> 00:05:51.380 and maybe you’ve been lucky and took a good one 00:05:51.380 --> 00:05:54.100 you would actually… I would say that some of the courses I took, 00:05:54.100 --> 00:05:57.780 they created some value for me. So one of the ways to look at this 00:05:57.780 --> 00:06:02.660 is actually to think about time as something that has opportunity cost. 00:06:02.660 --> 00:06:06.180 So if I’m spending my time doing this online course I’m not spending it 00:06:06.180 --> 00:06:11.030 e.g. earning money. I’m also not spending it doing something leisurely 00:06:11.030 --> 00:06:17.749 that is fun for me. And these guys, Brynjolfsson 00:06:17.749 --> 00:06:21.050 – I’m sorry I don’t know how to pronounce it exactly, 00:06:21.050 --> 00:06:26.110 he sounds Swedish, possibly – and ohh, in 2012 00:06:26.110 --> 00:06:33.020 they tried to get an idea of how much consumer surplus 00:06:33.020 --> 00:06:38.950 these online courses actually create. Which isn’t at all 00:06:38.950 --> 00:06:44.360 reflected in the GDP. And you see that in some models 00:06:44.360 --> 00:06:49.550 it would be 5% of GDP for these online courses alone. 00:06:49.550 --> 00:06:56.750 Even if we take their more... most conservative model which is $4.18 billion 00:06:56.750 --> 00:06:59.729 on average for the years 2008-2011, 00:06:59.729 --> 00:07:03.890 that’s still a pretty significant chunk of economic welfare 00:07:03.890 --> 00:07:07.780 that’s somehow being created that is not reflected in GDP 00:07:07.780 --> 00:07:11.770 because GDP is only stuff that you actually pay money for. 00:07:11.770 --> 00:07:14.919 Another example that we might think of is Wikipedia. 00:07:14.919 --> 00:07:19.160 Now Wikipedia has a certain cost of operating: obviously the servers and stuff. 00:07:19.160 --> 00:07:22.990 But because most people contributing to Wikipedia are actually volunteers 00:07:22.990 --> 00:07:25.910 the cost of operating does not really reflect 00:07:25.910 --> 00:07:30.250 the true value Wikipedia creates. And one of the… 00:07:30.250 --> 00:07:32.860 even if you don’t want to say… even if you don’t agree 00:07:32.860 --> 00:07:37.401 that time has opportunity cost, what about the money that you don’t spend 00:07:37.401 --> 00:07:43.800 on encyclopedias? How many of you guys have encyclopedias at home? 00:07:43.800 --> 00:07:46.210 OK, that’s more than I expected! 00:07:46.210 --> 00:07:49.260 How many of you guys have recent encyclopedias at home? 00:07:49.260 --> 00:07:53.580 That’s a little less, this is kind of more what I was expecting. 00:07:53.580 --> 00:07:57.880 And now, my family also… we also have an encyclopedia at home. 00:07:57.880 --> 00:08:02.720 I think it’s from 1985 or something. And before this encyclopedia 00:08:02.720 --> 00:08:06.210 we would regularly update an encyclopedia, we would regularly go out and buy 00:08:06.210 --> 00:08:09.840 a new encyclopedia because knowledge changed, obviously. 00:08:09.840 --> 00:08:14.410 But ever since probably 1990, we just didn’t bother. 00:08:14.410 --> 00:08:20.630 So, assuming an encyclopedia might, like a physical book, might cost €100. 00:08:20.630 --> 00:08:24.400 And assuming sort of 2/3 of all households in Germany 00:08:24.400 --> 00:08:28.100 have had an encyclopedia at one point. 00:08:28.100 --> 00:08:31.710 We’re looking at 13 million households at this point. 00:08:31.710 --> 00:08:35.630 Now you don’t buy an encyclopedia every year but you might buy it 00:08:35.630 --> 00:08:40.679 every ten years. So in order to simplify this we can say, every year 00:08:40.679 --> 00:08:46.010 1.3 million households buy an encyclopedia on average. 00:08:46.010 --> 00:08:52.680 1.3 million times €100, so we’re at €130 million 00:08:52.680 --> 00:08:57.680 of economic welfare, of something that people were willing to spend money for 00:08:57.680 --> 00:09:01.350 that they’re not spending money for anymore because of Wikipedia, because now that 00:09:01.350 --> 00:09:05.930 we have Wikipedia most of the encyclopedias aren’t actually useful for us anymore 00:09:05.930 --> 00:09:10.100 because the knowledge that we have, the knowledge that they would have 00:09:10.100 --> 00:09:18.760 would be outdated very, very soon and Wikipedia tends to be more up to date. 00:09:18.760 --> 00:09:23.550 Well, that was from the consumer’s side. But what about the business side? 00:09:23.550 --> 00:09:29.319 There’s a lot of research on whether the internet actually increases productivity 00:09:29.319 --> 00:09:33.500 for businesses or not. Well, I don’t really want to go into that debate because 00:09:33.500 --> 00:09:38.209 it’s a really long tedious debate that is kind of focused on “Well, you did this 00:09:38.209 --> 00:09:42.110 method wrong”, or “You did this wrong”, and “Well, I don’t think your argument 00:09:42.110 --> 00:09:47.410 makes sense”. So it’s very… I don’t like this kind of debate. I really like to go 00:09:47.410 --> 00:09:51.720 deeper in things. But one of the things that I found was that a lot of businesses 00:09:51.720 --> 00:09:59.219 do rely on the internet by now. Now we can see on this graph that most firms, 00:09:59.219 --> 00:10:06.199 overall about 70% of firms actually use the email to communicate. 00:10:06.199 --> 00:10:09.550 Now email obviously only works if you have internet, so they need 00:10:09.550 --> 00:10:16.450 some sort of access to internet in order for their current business model to work. 00:10:16.450 --> 00:10:22.110 Now this was just some short ideas on sort of what can the internet mean for 00:10:22.110 --> 00:10:26.149 the economy. And now I want to talk about Internet censorship, just a little bit. 00:10:26.149 --> 00:10:33.620 Now, I’m not a censorship expert. I’m just someone who read a lot of papers about it, 00:10:33.620 --> 00:10:37.660 and who was very interested in what kind of effects this has beyond sort of 00:10:37.660 --> 00:10:43.890 the obvious “people don’t have access to political information”. 00:10:43.890 --> 00:10:47.709 So first a definition. ‘Internet censorship’ is the controller suppression 00:10:47.709 --> 00:10:50.889 of what can be accessed, published or viewed on the Internet 00:10:50.889 --> 00:10:55.269 enacted by regulators or on their own initiative. Now, in trying to conceptualize 00:10:55.269 --> 00:10:59.269 internet censorship, for me, personally, there’s two dimensions that are 00:10:59.269 --> 00:11:03.840 very important. One is how targeted is this internet censorship? 00:11:03.840 --> 00:11:11.509 Now, you could, in theory, basically have internet censorship 00:11:11.509 --> 00:11:15.339 that is very, very targeted, which you see in some cases. 00:11:15.339 --> 00:11:18.729 Or you can have censorship that isn’t targeted at all, like in Egypt. 00:11:18.729 --> 00:11:23.560 They just decided to close the internet down, basically, for a day. 00:11:23.560 --> 00:11:28.249 That isn’t very targeted censorship, obviously. The other thing to look at 00:11:28.249 --> 00:11:32.980 is how widespread is it? So if you are a business or if you’re a normal consumer 00:11:32.980 --> 00:11:38.939 how probable is it that you would come (?) something that’s censored? 00:11:38.939 --> 00:11:43.180 Now, obviously, if you’re in China it’s a lot more probable that you would 00:11:43.180 --> 00:11:47.159 try to access something that’s censored than if you’re in Germany. Even though 00:11:47.159 --> 00:11:52.720 Germany also does some censorship. And the way I like to conceptualize it is 00:11:52.720 --> 00:11:58.019 to be kind of on a continuum. So I don’t look… I don’t say “Well, either 00:11:58.019 --> 00:12:01.649 there’s censorship or there isn’t censorship”. What I’m trying to say is 00:12:01.649 --> 00:12:06.930 “Censorship has a big spectrum of things that can happen”. 00:12:06.930 --> 00:12:12.809 These are some types of Internet censorship that have different sort of implications. 00:12:12.809 --> 00:12:16.309 I don’t want to go through them in detail because I think we’ve heard some really 00:12:16.309 --> 00:12:21.540 interesting talks on Internet censorship already. But this is kind of 00:12:21.540 --> 00:12:26.540 interesting or important for the model that I’m trying to build. 00:12:26.540 --> 00:12:30.370 But before trying to build my model, first some more motivation. 00:12:30.370 --> 00:12:33.980 I was trying to look at “is there any evidence that it would have 00:12:33.980 --> 00:12:39.819 an economic impact?”. And there actually is a study that’s conducted by sort of 00:12:39.819 --> 00:12:45.819 lobbying organizations, so obviously should be taken with a grain of salt. 00:12:45.819 --> 00:12:50.310 But it is quite interesting, and it shows that there seems to be a correlation 00:12:50.310 --> 00:12:59.499 between freedom and how good the economic impact of internet is. 00:12:59.499 --> 00:13:03.769 This is just a simple correlation. You can see that there’s a really good line 00:13:03.769 --> 00:13:09.920 going through it. They did do some controlling for GDP per capita, so 00:13:09.920 --> 00:13:16.580 for development level. But it still seems quite rudimentary, to be honest. 00:13:16.580 --> 00:13:23.979 The data that they use is quite bad because it is very, very… 00:13:23.979 --> 00:13:30.289 it’s just not finally granular enough, and a lot of it is kind of… someone rating… 00:13:30.289 --> 00:13:34.809 so “How do you think the economic…”, “How do you think Internet 00:13:34.809 --> 00:13:39.699 impacts the economy in this country?” And then this is the data that they use, 00:13:39.699 --> 00:13:48.069 to some degree. So it seemed very… it didn’t really seem like a good, final answer. 00:13:48.069 --> 00:13:53.529 So I’m trying to set up my own model. And in my model I have a government 00:13:53.529 --> 00:13:57.709 that chooses the type of censorship. And for this type of censorship that it chooses 00:13:57.709 --> 00:14:02.509 it pays a cost. Because we all know censorship can be very expensive. 00:14:02.509 --> 00:14:09.709 And in my model for now the only type of expenses that I calculate are actual 00:14:09.709 --> 00:14:16.989 manpower and technology expenses. I don’t calculate reputation expenses at this point. 00:14:16.989 --> 00:14:24.209 There is… there are firms in n industries. Now this n is kind of not a fixed number 00:14:24.209 --> 00:14:30.629 but instead is a number that can fluctuate depending on the kind of country 00:14:30.629 --> 00:14:37.879 I’m trying to model. And these industries distinguish themselves by their 00:14:37.879 --> 00:14:42.459 information intensity, or what I like to call ‘information intensity’. Basically 00:14:42.459 --> 00:14:47.540 I look at information as a commodity. And what I’m trying to decide, or 00:14:47.540 --> 00:14:51.910 the way I distinguish different kinds of industry is how important is information 00:14:51.910 --> 00:14:56.279 as a commodity, as opposed to other kinds of commodities that are important 00:14:56.279 --> 00:15:01.160 for this industry. So let’s look at information intensity equals Zero. 00:15:01.160 --> 00:15:05.259 Like if we don’t really… if information as a commodity really isn’t important, 00:15:05.259 --> 00:15:09.720 especially sort of conveyed information, transmitted information. We can 00:15:09.720 --> 00:15:14.309 think of traditional agriculture. Now I know today’s agriculture tends to be 00:15:14.309 --> 00:15:18.859 large-scale, and there’s a lot of technology involved. But if you look at 00:15:18.859 --> 00:15:24.170 very traditional agriculture that we still might see happening in some parts 00:15:24.170 --> 00:15:30.060 of Africa there usually is very, very little information transmission involved. 00:15:30.060 --> 00:15:34.069 And most of the information transmission that is involved is actually mostly through 00:15:34.069 --> 00:15:40.189 word of mouth. So that would be a case of information intensity of very close to Zero. 00:15:40.189 --> 00:15:43.790 And then if we look at information intensity of 1 where basically the internet is 00:15:43.790 --> 00:15:48.759 the most… or information is the most important commodity. Internet businesses 00:15:48.759 --> 00:15:54.839 themselves would… obviously qualify here, – sorry – like, let’s look at Facebook 00:15:54.839 --> 00:15:59.899 and other kinds of businesses like this. And in between we have sort of industrial 00:15:59.899 --> 00:16:03.339 companies in the modern world. Now if we’re closer to the Zero end 00:16:03.339 --> 00:16:07.639 of the spectrum we might be at 0.2 .. 0.3, something like this, 00:16:07.639 --> 00:16:15.449 we might be in traditional garment factories. They do have information needs, 00:16:15.449 --> 00:16:20.720 they get their cuts and stuff from the Internet by now, or by email. 00:16:20.720 --> 00:16:25.129 But once they have them they basically stay the same for a couple of weeks or months. 00:16:25.129 --> 00:16:30.409 So there’s a very low information requirement. On the other side, 00:16:30.409 --> 00:16:35.999 closer to 0.8 or something like that we have high-tech, 00:16:35.999 --> 00:16:41.220 especially software manufacturing, so to speak. Information and being able 00:16:41.220 --> 00:16:44.930 to transmit this information is very important. Now, in between we might look 00:16:44.930 --> 00:16:51.259 at traditional industrial companies like automobile manufacturing 00:16:51.259 --> 00:16:56.000 that might be somewhere in between. And before the game, or before… 00:16:56.000 --> 00:17:00.160 or at the first run of the model ‘service level’ and ‘globalization level’ 00:17:00.160 --> 00:17:05.599 are randomly distributed. The information intensity of industries is also kind of 00:17:05.599 --> 00:17:11.799 randomly distributed, but not in a true random fashion. Because when looking 00:17:11.799 --> 00:17:15.500 in the wild, sort of what kind of economies exist, most of them… 00:17:15.500 --> 00:17:19.199 the information intensity of one industry is kind of correlated with 00:17:19.199 --> 00:17:23.449 information intensities of other industries in this country. Like in Germany 00:17:23.449 --> 00:17:29.269 we’re very known for a certain type of industry that we have quite a lot of, 00:17:29.269 --> 00:17:35.440 which is manufacturing, very high-technology manufacturing. So we have more industries 00:17:35.440 --> 00:17:40.450 in this area but we have less traditional agriculture, for example. 00:17:40.450 --> 00:17:44.669 So having a true random distribution wouldn’t work. In addition the service level 00:17:44.669 --> 00:17:49.919 and the globalization level are randomly distributed as kind of external variables. 00:17:49.919 --> 00:17:55.090 Obviously, this is a simplification because I can’t really start at the beginning like 00:17:55.090 --> 00:17:58.870 I can’t say: “Oh well, I’ll start, I don’t know, 2000 BC 00:17:58.870 --> 00:18:04.190 with a very blank economy, and then something happens and something happens 00:18:04.190 --> 00:18:08.320 and something happens”. That’s just not realistic. So in order to get a better idea 00:18:08.320 --> 00:18:12.830 of what happens with different types of economies, what I’m doing is I’m running 00:18:12.830 --> 00:18:18.899 this game or this model again and again. And having these random parameters 00:18:18.899 --> 00:18:24.539 basically changed everytime. So on average there should be… 00:18:24.539 --> 00:18:29.289 there should be usable results. 00:18:29.289 --> 00:18:35.230 Now what this is actually missing is the consumer as a labourer. 00:18:35.230 --> 00:18:40.090 So I don’t really have ‘labour’ reflected in here. A more complete model would have 00:18:40.090 --> 00:18:44.080 that reflected. But it’s not the most interesting aspect of my model, so 00:18:44.080 --> 00:18:49.940 I’m not presenting this here, basically. 00:18:49.940 --> 00:18:56.080 Now, let’s look at what this would mean for firms. In my model 00:18:56.080 --> 00:18:59.649 what kind of things would I expect thinking through it logically which is 00:18:59.649 --> 00:19:04.820 always the first step when trying to model something. First of all if we have 00:19:04.820 --> 00:19:10.130 an information intensity of something greater than Zero but smaller than One. 00:19:10.130 --> 00:19:14.410 Because the information intensity being close to One is kind of a special case 00:19:14.410 --> 00:19:18.520 that I’ll be talking about later on. Internet censorship increases the cost 00:19:18.520 --> 00:19:22.360 and uncertainty of information. And of course that is more important 00:19:22.360 --> 00:19:27.850 the more important information is for this certain industry. 00:19:27.850 --> 00:19:33.850 So for a traditional garment factory internet censorship might be a lot 00:19:33.850 --> 00:19:41.000 less important than for a semiconductor factory that has to receive 00:19:41.000 --> 00:19:47.090 new blueprints every day or every month or something. The second thing is 00:19:47.090 --> 00:19:51.559 the more globalized the economy as a whole is the more costly internet censorship 00:19:51.559 --> 00:19:58.490 will be. Similar reasoning. 00:19:58.490 --> 00:20:02.990 And another thing for firms is the less focused the censorship 00:20:02.990 --> 00:20:07.640 the higher the cost. Now this assumes that the censorship or the goal of censorship 00:20:07.640 --> 00:20:14.370 usually isn’t to turn down firms or to make sure that firms don’t succeed. 00:20:14.370 --> 00:20:19.820 So if censorship is very focused firms tend to be affected less 00:20:19.820 --> 00:20:25.149 which makes their associated cost less. Now of course we can argue, well, 00:20:25.149 --> 00:20:29.399 firms can circumvent censorship, and they can do that for sure. But it is expensive 00:20:29.399 --> 00:20:35.299 to do that. If you’ve ever tried a VPN in China e.g., first, buying the VPN 00:20:35.299 --> 00:20:40.919 is expensive. Then, having someone sort of make sure that the VPN works is expensive, 00:20:40.919 --> 00:20:44.009 every couple of months you need to change it because the Chinese Government decides, 00:20:44.009 --> 00:20:52.549 well, this VPN shouldn’t work anymore. So it’s a very expensive and uncertain thing, 00:20:52.549 --> 00:20:57.909 really. For firms in ‘information intensity = 1’ 00:20:57.909 --> 00:21:02.940 it obviously also increases the cost of operating. Some of these firms actually 00:21:02.940 --> 00:21:07.970 carry out some censorship for governments. We have seen that happening more recently. 00:21:07.970 --> 00:21:12.570 But there might actually be some firms that have a relative advantage, especially 00:21:12.570 --> 00:21:16.820 domestic firms often have a relative advantage due to the censorship because 00:21:16.820 --> 00:21:20.950 they know the regulators better, they know how to deal with it, they might have 00:21:20.950 --> 00:21:25.039 less need to circumvent, actually. And even if they do need to circumvent 00:21:25.039 --> 00:21:29.539 it’s easier for them because they speak the language etc. 00:21:29.539 --> 00:21:34.090 This is actually a special case that I’ll be talking about a little bit later as well. 00:21:34.090 --> 00:21:38.460 For the government – I’ve said that censorship is costly. But moreover, 00:21:38.460 --> 00:21:43.100 the more targeted and accurate censorship is the more manpower and technology intensive 00:21:43.100 --> 00:21:50.389 it actually is. This is a finding by Leberknight et al. in a research paper. 00:21:50.389 --> 00:21:54.480 I think they’re electrical engineers, and they calculated through different types 00:21:54.480 --> 00:22:00.350 of censorships and how expensive it would be to scale them up. So that is actually 00:22:00.350 --> 00:22:03.479 a really interesting finding because it shows that for governments 00:22:03.479 --> 00:22:10.460 having sort of less targeted censorship is less costly. But this is the kind of 00:22:10.460 --> 00:22:17.039 censorship that is actually most affecting in a negative way to firms, 00:22:17.039 --> 00:22:20.990 in an economy. So that’s kind of not a result that we would really want 00:22:20.990 --> 00:22:24.919 because the incentives don’t line up in that way. And economists love to talk 00:22:24.919 --> 00:22:29.169 about incentives, obviously. Now for consumers, they would obviously get 00:22:29.169 --> 00:22:33.090 less benefits through the internet, the benefits that I’ve talked about before. 00:22:33.090 --> 00:22:38.430 And also businesses often pass on the cost to consumers. 00:22:38.430 --> 00:22:43.350 Now however, some countries still benefit from internet censorship. 00:22:43.350 --> 00:22:45.970 I’ve talked mostly about why it’s costly to do it, 00:22:45.970 --> 00:22:48.700 and I think it is costly in most cases. 00:22:48.700 --> 00:22:53.210 But developing countries that start out at low service and low globalization levels 00:22:53.210 --> 00:22:58.950 usually have… in these kind of situations internet censorship has less of an impact, 00:22:58.950 --> 00:23:04.370 less of a negative impact. And censorship can actually act 00:23:04.370 --> 00:23:08.880 as protectionism. In information intensive industries governments can use this kind 00:23:08.880 --> 00:23:13.650 of censorship to push domestic industries and enable catch-up growth. Now there 00:23:13.650 --> 00:23:16.820 are a couple of further prerequisites. First of all, the country needs to be 00:23:16.820 --> 00:23:20.640 large enough so that these information intensive industries 00:23:20.640 --> 00:23:23.640 have a domestic market as well. 00:23:23.640 --> 00:23:27.379 Obviously. And then also only targeted censorship can serve as 00:23:27.379 --> 00:23:32.159 protectionism. The only other way would be if you decided on a domestic intranet and 00:23:32.159 --> 00:23:38.059 basically closed your entire intranet off to the world. Which is kind of difficult. 00:23:38.059 --> 00:23:41.850 But what about the long-term effects of that? Would they still be positive 00:23:41.850 --> 00:23:47.669 for the government? Now, I’m using ‘positive’ in a very… sort of something 00:23:47.669 --> 00:23:51.820 that should be taken with a grain of salt, obviously. And what I did is I looked 00:23:51.820 --> 00:23:57.330 at China. Obviously, I’m a China watcher. So I’m really interested in China. And 00:23:57.330 --> 00:24:02.190 this is kind of where my interest started. And I’m really trying to find a framework 00:24:02.190 --> 00:24:07.219 where China isn’t the exception but instead China kind of fits into the model. 00:24:07.219 --> 00:24:13.129 What we see is the Chinese government has outsourced much if its censorship to these 00:24:13.129 --> 00:24:19.000 internet companies. Baidu, Sina weibo, Tencent probably would not exist by now, 00:24:19.000 --> 00:24:24.820 actually, if the censorship didn’t exist. And what we actually see now is that 00:24:24.820 --> 00:24:29.750 WeChat e.g. is going global. It has more functionality than Whatsapp 00:24:29.750 --> 00:24:35.799 and they’re trying to get out. But as I’ll be talking about later on a little bit 00:24:35.799 --> 00:24:41.810 the censorship is starting to be a problem for these companies that used to benefit. 00:24:41.810 --> 00:24:46.840 There’s some things about Chinese… about the character of Chinese Internet censorship 00:24:46.840 --> 00:24:54.409 that is relevant here. But what about the future? Now first it’s difficult to 00:24:54.409 --> 00:24:58.660 innovate with this kind of censorship. And this kind of insular education that we see 00:24:58.660 --> 00:25:03.450 also makes innovation, real innovation, very difficult. In China e.g. Github 00:25:03.450 --> 00:25:07.631 is blocked most of the time. That makes kind of collaborating, especially in 00:25:07.631 --> 00:25:11.730 coding environments, very, very hard. 00:25:11.730 --> 00:25:14.490 Second, we see more global internet enabled 00:25:14.490 --> 00:25:20.059 supply chains in the world. So if we have these global Internet-enabled supply chains 00:25:20.059 --> 00:25:25.669 having internet censorship turns out to be more of a disadvantage the more globalized 00:25:25.669 --> 00:25:31.879 these supply chains actually become. And information becomes the most important 00:25:31.879 --> 00:25:36.230 commodity all throughout China. Now this of course also makes Internet censorship 00:25:36.230 --> 00:25:41.000 more costly for the economy. What about possible positives? So what could work 00:25:41.000 --> 00:25:45.500 in the Chinese government’s favour? First, the Chinese intranet is actually pretty 00:25:45.500 --> 00:25:50.429 attractive to most people. Most people don’t try to go outside, even like 00:25:50.429 --> 00:25:55.269 they don’t even know that they can’t. They just don’t want to do it. Second, the IoT, 00:25:55.269 --> 00:25:59.429 where machines communicate with each other doesn’t need to be affected because 00:25:59.429 --> 00:26:04.820 most of the censorship that we see happening could be reworked in a way 00:26:04.820 --> 00:26:08.599 that doesn’t affect machine-to-machine communication. And that wouldn’t be 00:26:08.599 --> 00:26:14.039 a problem for what the censorship intends to do which is sort of suppress political 00:26:14.039 --> 00:26:20.669 opposition. And a third, the government wants an economy more focused on domestic 00:26:20.669 --> 00:26:24.230 consumption. So if they want to do this then censorship might actually be good 00:26:24.230 --> 00:26:30.669 for that. Now, for me, what I found out when doing this research is first, 00:26:30.669 --> 00:26:34.709 standard economic models really aren’t suited for this kind of question. Because 00:26:34.709 --> 00:26:38.370 they tend to use GDP, and I’ve told you why GDP really is not a good measure 00:26:38.370 --> 00:26:43.419 for that. Second, the next step that I’ll be doing is agent-based modeling. 00:26:43.419 --> 00:26:48.910 But I would really like to feed my models with some reliable data. And I can’t 00:26:48.910 --> 00:26:53.400 really find any of that. I can find some data going back a couple of years 00:26:53.400 --> 00:26:57.779 on, like, is there censorship, is there no censorship. But I can’t really find any 00:26:57.779 --> 00:27:02.150 good data that distinguishes between different types of censorship, which would 00:27:02.150 --> 00:27:06.440 be really important for the kind of research that I really want to carry out 00:27:06.440 --> 00:27:11.610 in the future. Thank you, guys. If you have questions you can ask now or 00:27:11.610 --> 00:27:15.129 you can come to me later, you can of course also send me an e-mail. 00:27:15.129 --> 00:27:18.719 I’m always happy to talk about this topic. 00:27:18.719 --> 00:27:27.529 applause 00:27:27.529 --> 00:27:32.000 Herald: Thank you very much for this talk. We have six microphones at the floor level 00:27:32.000 --> 00:27:35.660 here, so if you have questions we have a very brief amount of time. 00:27:35.660 --> 00:27:40.430 Please line up at the microphones. We have microphone no. 2 over here. 00:27:40.430 --> 00:27:46.480 Question: I want to mention one thing. Always when talking about China censorship 00:27:46.480 --> 00:27:51.299 this censorship applies to China main land. So it’s not Hong Kong and not Taiwan. 00:27:51.299 --> 00:27:51.959 Toni: Yes. 00:27:51.959 --> 00:27:55.769 Question: And my question I want to ask is: 00:27:55.769 --> 00:27:59.219 What do you think about productivity of work? 00:27:59.219 --> 00:28:05.200 So e.g. if you shut down Facebook do you think this would increase working 00:28:05.200 --> 00:28:08.059 productivity? Toni laughs 00:28:08.059 --> 00:28:13.010 applause Toni: That’s a really interesting question, 00:28:13.010 --> 00:28:16.470 and something that I haven’t seen anywhere in literature. There is a big literature 00:28:16.470 --> 00:28:21.970 discussion about what the internet as such means for productivity, and that’s 00:28:21.970 --> 00:28:26.820 kind of both ways. Now, one of the things to look at is that just because you 00:28:26.820 --> 00:28:31.200 shut down Facebook doesn’t mean you shut down any sort of social network. 00:28:31.200 --> 00:28:36.389 And I do think that if people use Facebook and suddenly aren’t able to use it anymore 00:28:36.389 --> 00:28:40.769 they would probably spend their resources trying to find new ways to access Facebook 00:28:40.769 --> 00:28:48.790 which would probably not exactly improve their productivity. 00:28:48.790 --> 00:28:52.299 Herald: Next question from microphone no. 2. 00:28:52.299 --> 00:28:57.909 Question: Would it make sense to have a model where firms use information 00:28:57.909 --> 00:29:02.480 as an input to a production function and then model censorship as a kind of tax 00:29:02.480 --> 00:29:08.109 on that. That will seem like standard new classical micro-econ one-on-one stuff? 00:29:08.109 --> 00:29:12.390 Toni: That would make sense. I’ve actually looked at this. One of the problems with 00:29:12.390 --> 00:29:17.730 doing that is that information as a commodity 00:29:17.730 --> 00:29:23.350 is very difficult to be used in this new classical way because you usually assume 00:29:23.350 --> 00:29:28.020 that everything is kind of friction-less. And if things are friction-less then 00:29:28.020 --> 00:29:31.619 information can’t really be a commodity because you assume that information 00:29:31.619 --> 00:29:36.500 basically gets transferred immediately, and without any sort of censorship. So 00:29:36.500 --> 00:29:39.590 we can talk about this a little bit later. Maybe you have some ideas that 00:29:39.590 --> 00:29:43.740 I haven’t found yet. It would be interesting. 00:29:43.740 --> 00:29:47.539 Herald: And the next question, as well, from microphone no. 2. 00:29:47.539 --> 00:29:53.629 Question: So, going the same direction: for GDP is rather defined what is 00:29:53.629 --> 00:29:59.429 the optimization problem for a government. For your further approaches what would be 00:29:59.429 --> 00:30:05.279 the optimization that a government like China does then. If you say e.g. Wikipedia 00:30:05.279 --> 00:30:08.950 which leaks out to all over the world but what is the government optimizing then? 00:30:08.950 --> 00:30:15.049 Toni: What I’m looking at is economic welfare as defined as producer and consumer surplus. 00:30:15.049 --> 00:30:22.539 And I assume that the government’s goal is to optimize economic welfare for both 00:30:22.539 --> 00:30:27.519 producers, consumers and also for itself as a producer and as a consumer. 00:30:27.519 --> 00:30:32.240 Question: So your criticism is more like you don’t have a good proxy, 00:30:32.240 --> 00:30:33.870 using GDP for economic welfare? 00:30:33.870 --> 00:30:36.870 Toni: Yes, yes. Okay. Thank you. 00:30:36.870 --> 00:30:38.370 Herald: I’m afraid we’re all out of time. 00:30:38.370 --> 00:30:40.350 Please give a warm round of applause to Toni! 00:30:40.350 --> 00:30:43.690 applause 00:30:43.690 --> 00:30:46.260 post-roll music 00:30:46.260 --> 00:30:50.540 Subtitles created by c3subtitles.de in the year 2017. Join, and help us!