WEBVTT 00:00:00.242 --> 00:00:03.867 ♪ [music] ♪ 00:00:09.433 --> 00:00:10.739 - [Alex] In our last two videos, 00:00:10.739 --> 00:00:13.109 we covered the elasticity of demand. 00:00:13.109 --> 00:00:16.296 We now turn to the elasticity of supply. 00:00:21.447 --> 00:00:23.108 The elasticity of supply measures 00:00:23.108 --> 00:00:28.448 how responsive the quantity supplied is to a change in the price. 00:00:28.775 --> 00:00:31.030 So it's almost the same as the elasticity of demand 00:00:31.030 --> 00:00:33.337 except instead of measuring the responsiveness 00:00:33.337 --> 00:00:35.504 of the quantity demanded, 00:00:35.504 --> 00:00:39.400 it measures the responsiveness of the quantity supplied 00:00:39.400 --> 00:00:41.009 to a change in price. 00:00:41.684 --> 00:00:45.020 A supply curve is said to be elastic 00:00:45.020 --> 00:00:50.277 when an increase in price increases the quantity supplied by a lot. 00:00:50.621 --> 00:00:52.140 And similarly vice versa, 00:00:52.140 --> 00:00:54.503 that is when a decrease in price 00:00:54.503 --> 00:00:57.673 decreases the quantity supplied by a lot 00:00:57.673 --> 00:01:00.062 then we say that the supply curve is elastic. 00:01:00.234 --> 00:01:04.477 So when the quantity supplied is very responsive to the price, 00:01:04.477 --> 00:01:06.574 we say the supply curve is elastic. 00:01:06.962 --> 00:01:08.907 When the same increase in price 00:01:08.907 --> 00:01:12.257 increases the quantity supplied by just a little 00:01:12.257 --> 00:01:15.087 then the supply curve is said to be inelastic. 00:01:15.417 --> 00:01:17.167 So when the quantity supplied 00:01:17.167 --> 00:01:20.617 doesn't vary very much with the price, 00:01:20.617 --> 00:01:23.098 the supply curve is inelastic. 00:01:24.812 --> 00:01:26.764 Here, we show this on a graph, 00:01:26.764 --> 00:01:29.645 so consider the first curve. 00:01:29.645 --> 00:01:33.627 A $10 increase in price on this curve -- 00:01:33.627 --> 00:01:35.990 here's the $10 increase in price -- 00:01:35.990 --> 00:01:40.322 increases the quantity supplied from 80 to 85 units, 00:01:40.322 --> 00:01:42.205 that is not by very much. 00:01:42.205 --> 00:01:46.225 On the other hand, on this more elastic supply curve, 00:01:46.225 --> 00:01:50.231 the same $10 increase in price 00:01:50.231 --> 00:01:53.034 increases the quantity supplied now 00:01:53.034 --> 00:01:56.111 from 80 units to 170 units. 00:01:56.111 --> 00:02:00.530 So you get a much bigger change in the quantity supplied 00:02:00.530 --> 00:02:05.002 from the same price increase when the supply curve is elastic 00:02:05.002 --> 00:02:07.443 compared to when it is inelastic. 00:02:07.948 --> 00:02:10.145 And again as with demand curves, 00:02:10.145 --> 00:02:13.150 elasticity is not the same thing as slope. 00:02:13.530 --> 00:02:15.699 Nevertheless, when you have two curves 00:02:15.699 --> 00:02:20.258 which go through a common point then the one which is flatter 00:02:20.258 --> 00:02:23.379 is more elastic at any given quantity. 00:02:23.379 --> 00:02:26.319 The one which is steeper is more inelastic. 00:02:26.568 --> 00:02:27.946 So we can always look at two curves 00:02:27.946 --> 00:02:32.497 and say this curve is more elastic than the steeper curve. 00:02:32.497 --> 00:02:35.068 And that will work for everything we're going to do in this class. 00:02:37.070 --> 00:02:41.172 So what are the major determinants of the elasticity of supply? 00:02:41.824 --> 00:02:43.873 First and most importantly, 00:02:43.873 --> 00:02:47.955 how do unit costs change with increased production? 00:02:48.323 --> 00:02:49.808 Second, the time horizon. 00:02:50.063 --> 00:02:53.065 Third, share of market for the inputs. 00:02:53.353 --> 00:02:55.662 And fourth, geographic scope. 00:02:55.662 --> 00:02:57.503 I'll explain each of these in turn. 00:02:58.564 --> 00:03:01.736 The main determinant of the elasticity of supply 00:03:01.736 --> 00:03:05.616 is how quickly per-unit costs increase 00:03:05.616 --> 00:03:07.747 with an increase in production. 00:03:08.005 --> 00:03:08.995 In particular, 00:03:09.293 --> 00:03:13.335 if increased production requires higher costs, 00:03:13.335 --> 00:03:15.666 then the supply curve will be inelastic. 00:03:15.666 --> 00:03:18.477 It will be steep if we're comparing two curves. 00:03:18.477 --> 00:03:19.676 On the other hand, 00:03:19.676 --> 00:03:22.990 if production can increase with constant cost 00:03:22.990 --> 00:03:27.086 or without increasing per unit cost very much, 00:03:27.086 --> 00:03:29.953 then the supply curve will be elastic. 00:03:30.197 --> 00:03:32.452 Let me give you two examples to make this clear. 00:03:33.356 --> 00:03:37.776 Compare the following two goods -- Picasso paintings and toothpicks. 00:03:38.283 --> 00:03:42.617 Which has an inelastic supply and which an elastic supply? 00:03:43.168 --> 00:03:46.639 Okay, so let's think about an increase in price. 00:03:47.345 --> 00:03:51.967 For which good is it easier to expand production? 00:03:52.386 --> 00:03:54.806 For which good can you increase production 00:03:54.806 --> 00:03:57.448 at low cost without pushing costs up? 00:03:58.692 --> 00:04:00.354 Clearly, toothpicks. 00:04:00.642 --> 00:04:02.597 So an increase in the price of toothpicks -- 00:04:02.597 --> 00:04:04.876 and you can make lots more toothpicks 00:04:04.876 --> 00:04:08.167 just by running an additional log down the sawmill. 00:04:08.167 --> 00:04:11.957 Many, many more toothpicks without an increase in cost. 00:04:11.957 --> 00:04:14.998 On the other hand, it's basically impossible 00:04:14.998 --> 00:04:19.436 to get an increase in the production of Picasso paintings. 00:04:19.436 --> 00:04:22.153 He simply isn't producing anymore. 00:04:22.398 --> 00:04:24.278 We may still have an increase 00:04:24.278 --> 00:04:28.302 in the market supply of Picasso paintings. 00:04:28.302 --> 00:04:30.922 Some people who have them in their homes 00:04:30.922 --> 00:04:32.686 will put them onto the market. 00:04:32.686 --> 00:04:36.005 But basically the supply of Picasso paintings 00:04:36.005 --> 00:04:37.913 is highly inelastic. 00:04:38.316 --> 00:04:40.835 The price can go up and up and up and up 00:04:40.835 --> 00:04:45.584 and you're not going to get very many more Picasso paintings. 00:04:46.169 --> 00:04:47.787 Once again on the other hand, 00:04:47.787 --> 00:04:50.714 if the price of toothpicks goes up even a little bit, 00:04:51.050 --> 00:04:52.706 you're going to get a lot more toothpicks. 00:04:52.918 --> 00:04:55.690 So the supply of toothpicks is elastic 00:04:55.690 --> 00:04:59.402 and the supply of Picasso paintings is inelastic. 00:05:00.757 --> 00:05:05.614 The time horizon influences the elasticity of supply for a good. 00:05:05.614 --> 00:05:08.713 and this is really just a logical consequence 00:05:08.713 --> 00:05:12.425 of the fact that elasticity depends upon cost 00:05:12.425 --> 00:05:14.790 and how easy it is to expand production. 00:05:15.070 --> 00:05:17.854 Immediately following a price increase, 00:05:17.854 --> 00:05:20.584 producers can expand production or output 00:05:20.584 --> 00:05:23.376 only by using their current capacity, 00:05:23.606 --> 00:05:27.035 so that tends to make supply more inelastic. 00:05:27.295 --> 00:05:31.935 So for example, if we're talking about grain production. 00:05:31.935 --> 00:05:35.735 If the price of grain goes up, well farmers can get 00:05:35.735 --> 00:05:38.645 a little bit more grain out of their field by threshing, 00:05:38.645 --> 00:05:40.744 by going over the fields more carefully, 00:05:40.744 --> 00:05:43.292 but they're not going to get a lot more 00:05:43.292 --> 00:05:45.748 until a year or two down the line, 00:05:45.748 --> 00:05:51.102 until after they've had a chance to plant more acres of grain. 00:05:51.691 --> 00:05:53.628 On the other hand as I just said, 00:05:53.628 --> 00:05:56.825 over time producers can expand their capacity. 00:05:57.137 --> 00:06:00.788 So in the short run, the elasticity of supply 00:06:00.788 --> 00:06:03.096 tends to be more inelastic 00:06:03.096 --> 00:06:07.285 because it's harder to expand output at the same cost. 00:06:07.285 --> 00:06:09.188 Over time, however, 00:06:09.188 --> 00:06:11.764 because producers can expand their capacity, 00:06:11.764 --> 00:06:14.549 the supply curve tends to be more elastic. 00:06:14.958 --> 00:06:17.650 So supply curve tend to be more elastic, 00:06:17.650 --> 00:06:21.953 the more time you give producers to respond to the price. 00:06:23.740 --> 00:06:26.439 The elasticity of supply also depends 00:06:26.439 --> 00:06:30.891 on whether the good in question is a small or big demander 00:06:30.891 --> 00:06:32.327 in its input markets. 00:06:32.638 --> 00:06:35.837 That is the industry's share of the demand for its inputs. 00:06:36.251 --> 00:06:37.237 Let me explain. 00:06:37.420 --> 00:06:40.140 Supply will tend to be more elastic 00:06:40.553 --> 00:06:42.989 when the industry is a small demander 00:06:42.989 --> 00:06:44.508 in its input markets. 00:06:44.880 --> 00:06:49.050 Because then supply can be expanded without causing a big increase 00:06:49.050 --> 00:06:52.162 in the demand for the industry's inputs. 00:06:52.438 --> 00:06:54.410 Let's go back to the toothpick example. 00:06:54.867 --> 00:06:58.804 One of the reasons why toothpicks have an elastic supply 00:06:58.804 --> 00:07:03.520 is because we can easily double the supply of toothpicks 00:07:03.520 --> 00:07:07.859 and have just a tiny impact on the demand for wood 00:07:07.859 --> 00:07:09.779 on the input into toothpicks. 00:07:10.141 --> 00:07:13.091 So we can double the supply of toothpicks 00:07:13.091 --> 00:07:16.838 and since toothpicks are just a small user of wood, 00:07:17.170 --> 00:07:18.885 we don't require much more wood 00:07:18.885 --> 00:07:21.771 so we're not going to increase the demand for wood very much 00:07:21.771 --> 00:07:24.282 when we increase the demand for toothpicks. 00:07:24.282 --> 00:07:27.062 Therefore the price of wood is not going to be pushed up 00:07:27.062 --> 00:07:29.997 when we demand more toothpicks. 00:07:29.997 --> 00:07:33.971 Therefore the quantity supplied of toothpicks 00:07:33.971 --> 00:07:36.754 can easily increase at the same price 00:07:36.754 --> 00:07:39.472 without increasing the cost of toothpicks. 00:07:40.413 --> 00:07:43.663 On the other hand, supply will tend to be inelastic 00:07:43.663 --> 00:07:47.345 when the industry is a big demander in its input markets. 00:07:47.840 --> 00:07:51.611 So again suppose that the demand for automobiles were to increase. 00:07:51.903 --> 00:07:54.113 In order to expand the supply of automobiles 00:07:54.113 --> 00:07:55.723 we need more steel, 00:07:56.537 --> 00:08:01.143 but automobiles are a big demander of steel. 00:08:01.407 --> 00:08:05.148 So when we want to increase the supply of automobiles, 00:08:05.148 --> 00:08:07.267 we're going to use a lot more steel 00:08:07.267 --> 00:08:09.583 that's going to push up the price of steel, 00:08:09.583 --> 00:08:12.183 therefore that's going to increase the price 00:08:12.183 --> 00:08:14.787 of an input into making automobiles 00:08:14.787 --> 00:08:17.793 which is going to push the price of automobiles up. 00:08:18.093 --> 00:08:21.955 Therefore the supply of automobiles will tend to be more inelastic 00:08:22.383 --> 00:08:25.524 because when we try and increase the supply of automobiles, 00:08:25.524 --> 00:08:28.940 we're going to increase the price of steel 00:08:28.940 --> 00:08:33.014 that increases the cost of producing automobiles. 00:08:34.167 --> 00:08:36.955 The geographic scope of the market is another determinant 00:08:36.955 --> 00:08:38.965 of the elasticity of supply. 00:08:39.353 --> 00:08:41.745 In particular, the narrower the scope of the market, 00:08:41.745 --> 00:08:44.119 the more elastic the supply. 00:08:44.489 --> 00:08:48.598 The wider the scope of the market, the less elastic the supply. 00:08:49.075 --> 00:08:53.979 For example, suppose that the demand for gasoline increases 00:08:53.979 --> 00:08:55.321 in Washington D.C., 00:08:55.321 --> 00:08:58.560 say more people are moving to the D.C. region. 00:08:59.025 --> 00:09:03.322 Well, that demand can easily be supplied 00:09:03.322 --> 00:09:06.809 by taking a little bit of gasoline from elsewhere in the country 00:09:06.809 --> 00:09:09.749 and we can increase the supply of gasoline 00:09:09.749 --> 00:09:12.159 in Washington, D.C. very easily 00:09:12.159 --> 00:09:15.558 without pushing up the price of gasoline hardly at all. 00:09:16.039 --> 00:09:17.249 On the other hand, 00:09:17.249 --> 00:09:20.029 if the worldwide demand of gasoline went up 00:09:20.029 --> 00:09:22.089 say because China is becoming richer, 00:09:22.089 --> 00:09:24.827 India is becoming richer. They're buying more automobiles. 00:09:24.827 --> 00:09:28.556 Well in that case, we're going to have to dig for more oil. 00:09:28.556 --> 00:09:30.228 We're going to have to search for more oil. 00:09:30.228 --> 00:09:32.220 That's going to be much more expensive 00:09:32.220 --> 00:09:35.875 to increase the supply of gasoline to the world 00:09:35.875 --> 00:09:38.429 than it is to increase the supply of gasoline 00:09:38.429 --> 00:09:40.529 to Washington, D.C. 00:09:40.870 --> 00:09:43.294 Again, both of these are simply a reflection 00:09:43.294 --> 00:09:45.279 of the fundamental idea -- 00:09:45.719 --> 00:09:48.950 Does an increase in the supply of a good, 00:09:48.950 --> 00:09:52.882 does that require a big increase in the cost of producing the good? 00:09:53.183 --> 00:09:57.094 So it's very easy to increase supply in Washington, D.C. 00:09:57.094 --> 00:09:59.450 or in a particular state and so forth. 00:09:59.450 --> 00:10:03.069 It's much more difficult to increase the total supply. 00:10:04.894 --> 00:10:06.524 Okay. Let's summarize. 00:10:06.524 --> 00:10:09.029 What makes a supply curve more elastic? 00:10:09.029 --> 00:10:11.790 Fundamentally, a supply curve will be elastic 00:10:11.790 --> 00:10:14.081 when it's easy to increase production 00:10:14.081 --> 00:10:17.523 at constant unit cost or when it's easy to increase production 00:10:17.523 --> 00:10:20.398 without increasing the unit cost very much. 00:10:21.095 --> 00:10:23.954 Supply curves tend to be more elastic in the long run 00:10:23.954 --> 00:10:25.361 compared to the short run. 00:10:25.361 --> 00:10:27.011 They tend to be more elastic 00:10:27.011 --> 00:10:32.271 when the good has a small share of the market for its inputs, 00:10:32.794 --> 00:10:34.830 so it doesn't raise the price of its inputs 00:10:34.830 --> 00:10:36.977 when the market expands. 00:10:36.977 --> 00:10:39.220 And goods tend to be more elastic 00:10:39.220 --> 00:10:42.035 when we're just talking about the local supply of a good 00:10:42.035 --> 00:10:46.486 rather than the global supply which tends to be less elastic. 00:10:47.327 --> 00:10:49.525 The elasticity of supply is defined 00:10:49.525 --> 00:10:52.509 as the percentage change in the quantity supplied 00:10:52.509 --> 00:10:55.490 divided by the percentage change in the price. 00:10:55.490 --> 00:10:59.607 So, that's exactly the same as for the elasticity of demand 00:10:59.607 --> 00:11:01.261 with the exception being that instead of talking 00:11:01.261 --> 00:11:02.912 about the quantity demanded, 00:11:02.912 --> 00:11:05.038 we're talking about the quantity supplied. 00:11:05.038 --> 00:11:07.701 In mathematical notation, the elasticity supply 00:11:07.701 --> 00:11:10.423 is the percentage, delta for change in, 00:11:10.423 --> 00:11:12.351 percent of change in the quantity supplied 00:11:12.351 --> 00:11:15.331 divided by the percent of change in the price. 00:11:16.839 --> 00:11:18.151 Here's an example. 00:11:18.151 --> 00:11:20.841 If the price of cocoa rises by 10% 00:11:20.841 --> 00:11:23.921 and the quantity supplied increases by 3%, 00:11:23.921 --> 00:11:27.009 then the elasticity of supply for cocoa is: 00:11:27.483 --> 00:11:31.833 So, elasticity percentage change in quantity supplied, that's 3%, 00:11:31.833 --> 00:11:35.282 divided by the percentage change in the price, 10%. 00:11:35.282 --> 00:11:38.459 So the elasticity must be 0.3. 00:11:39.872 --> 00:11:41.318 Here's our midpoint formula. 00:11:41.318 --> 00:11:44.963 Again practically the same as that for the elasticity of demand, 00:11:44.963 --> 00:11:47.540 only we're dealing with the quantity supplied 00:11:47.540 --> 00:11:49.622 rather than the quantity demanded. 00:11:49.622 --> 00:11:51.632 So the percentage change in quantity supplied 00:11:51.632 --> 00:11:53.380 is the change in quantity supplied 00:11:53.380 --> 00:11:56.294 divided by the average quantity times 100. 00:11:56.294 --> 00:11:58.840 The percentage change in price is the change in price 00:11:58.840 --> 00:12:01.063 divided by the average price times 100. 00:12:01.063 --> 00:12:03.843 The hundreds cancel out so we're left with this formula 00:12:03.843 --> 00:12:05.363 where the change in quantity 00:12:05.363 --> 00:12:08.189 is quantity after minus quantity before 00:12:08.189 --> 00:12:09.780 over the average quantity. 00:12:10.180 --> 00:12:13.346 Price after minus price before over the average price. 00:12:13.677 --> 00:12:15.036 Let's do an example. 00:12:16.154 --> 00:12:19.983 At the initial price of $10, the quantity supplied is 100. 00:12:19.983 --> 00:12:24.053 When the price rises to $20, the quantity supplied is 110. 00:12:24.053 --> 00:12:25.793 So let's remember our formula -- 00:12:25.793 --> 00:12:27.460 change in quantity over average quantity, 00:12:27.460 --> 00:12:29.273 change in price over average price. 00:12:29.273 --> 00:12:33.372 So the quantity after is 110, 00:12:33.372 --> 00:12:35.482 the quantity before is 100, 00:12:35.482 --> 00:12:38.673 so the change in quantity is 110 minus 100. 00:12:38.673 --> 00:12:40.413 This is the average quantity. 00:12:40.413 --> 00:12:43.583 The change in price is 20 minus 10. 00:12:43.583 --> 00:12:46.483 Just make sure that since we started here 00:12:46.483 --> 00:12:49.613 with the quantity after being 110, 00:12:49.613 --> 00:12:52.322 that's associated with the price after of 20 00:12:52.322 --> 00:12:53.814 so put the 20 first. 00:12:53.814 --> 00:12:57.084 20 minus 10 is 10 over the average price, 00:12:57.084 --> 00:12:58.588 etc., etc., etc. 00:12:58.588 --> 00:13:00.590 You can calculate the numbers and what you find 00:13:00.590 --> 00:13:04.736 is the elasticity is .143. 00:13:06.193 --> 00:13:07.962 As with the elasticity of demand, 00:13:07.962 --> 00:13:10.554 if the elasticity of supply is less than one, 00:13:10.554 --> 00:13:12.664 the supply curve is said to inelastic. 00:13:12.664 --> 00:13:13.975 If it's greater than one, 00:13:13.975 --> 00:13:16.094 the supply curve is said to be elastic. 00:13:16.094 --> 00:13:19.192 If it's equal to one, it's said to be unit elastic. 00:13:19.192 --> 00:13:23.715 Okay, that's it for the mechanics of the elasticity of supply. 00:13:23.715 --> 00:13:24.825 What we're going to do next 00:13:24.825 --> 00:13:28.262 is applications of the elasticity of supply. 00:13:28.262 --> 00:13:31.381 This is an extremely important part of the course 00:13:31.381 --> 00:13:33.734 so make sure you do follow the applications, 00:13:33.734 --> 00:13:37.020 learning how to apply these ideas in the real world, 00:13:37.020 --> 00:13:38.905 showing what the real world consequences 00:13:38.905 --> 00:13:42.593 of these different elasticities are is extremely important. 00:13:42.593 --> 00:13:44.735 That's what we're going to do next and that will bring us back 00:13:44.735 --> 00:13:47.295 to that question we asked at the very beginning -- 00:13:47.650 --> 00:13:52.715 How can we analyze something like the redemption of slaves, 00:13:52.715 --> 00:13:56.146 whether this is going to be a good policy or a bad policy? 00:13:56.146 --> 00:13:58.935 The elasticity of supply turns out to be critical 00:13:58.935 --> 00:14:00.623 to understanding that question, 00:14:00.623 --> 00:14:02.517 that's what we're going to look at next. 00:14:02.517 --> 00:14:03.568 Thanks. 00:14:04.985 --> 00:14:06.294 - [Narrator] If you want to test yourself, 00:14:06.294 --> 00:14:07.884 click "Practice Questions." 00:14:08.727 --> 00:14:11.991 Or if you're ready to move on, just click "Next Video." 00:14:12.255 --> 00:14:16.039 ♪ [music] ♪