WEBVTT 00:00:00.153 --> 00:00:05.716 ♪ [music] ♪ 00:00:09.468 --> 00:00:10.638 - [Tyler] In our last video, 00:00:10.638 --> 00:00:13.798 we saw that price discrimination is good for the monopolist. 00:00:13.798 --> 00:00:15.227 It increases profits, 00:00:15.227 --> 00:00:17.512 but what about for society as a whole, 00:00:17.512 --> 00:00:20.638 does price discrimination increase social welfare? 00:00:20.638 --> 00:00:22.557 That's the topic of today's talk. 00:00:27.769 --> 00:00:30.294 It's complicated, but here's a rule of thumb -- 00:00:30.294 --> 00:00:32.908 if price discrimination increases output 00:00:32.908 --> 00:00:35.186 then it's very likely to be beneficial, 00:00:35.186 --> 00:00:37.059 to increase social welfare. 00:00:37.059 --> 00:00:39.169 If output, however, does not increase 00:00:39.169 --> 00:00:41.688 then welfare probably is reduced. 00:00:41.688 --> 00:00:42.969 Let's give some intuition 00:00:42.969 --> 00:00:46.098 for when price discrimination increases welfare. 00:00:46.098 --> 00:00:47.798 Think about our previous example 00:00:47.798 --> 00:00:50.638 of the pharmaceutical company GSK 00:00:50.638 --> 00:00:52.599 setting a high drug price in Europe 00:00:52.599 --> 00:00:54.888 and a lower drug price in Africa. 00:00:54.888 --> 00:00:58.554 Suppose that GSK were forced to charge only one price. 00:00:58.983 --> 00:01:02.019 Do you think it would charge closer to the European price 00:01:02.019 --> 00:01:04.290 of $12.50 per pill 00:01:04.290 --> 00:01:07.681 or closer to the African price of 50 cents per pill? 00:01:08.124 --> 00:01:09.759 What's more likely to happen 00:01:09.759 --> 00:01:12.938 if GSK is required to set only one price? 00:01:13.440 --> 00:01:15.381 If they can't price discriminate, 00:01:15.381 --> 00:01:19.509 GSK very likely will simply abandon the African market 00:01:19.509 --> 00:01:22.101 where they weren't making that much profit anyway 00:01:22.101 --> 00:01:24.009 and set a single world price 00:01:24.009 --> 00:01:26.219 pretty close to the European level. 00:01:26.707 --> 00:01:29.801 People sometimes think that if only everyone were allowed 00:01:29.801 --> 00:01:33.048 to import pharmaceuticals to the United States 00:01:33.048 --> 00:01:36.200 from Canada, Mexico, or Africa where they're cheaper, 00:01:36.200 --> 00:01:38.441 then we would all enjoy lower prices. 00:01:38.902 --> 00:01:40.038 Probably not. 00:01:40.200 --> 00:01:43.451 If smuggling or legal re-importation of pharmaceuticals 00:01:43.451 --> 00:01:44.969 were to become more common, 00:01:44.969 --> 00:01:48.726 then pharmaceutical companies would stop price discriminating 00:01:48.726 --> 00:01:50.934 and set higher prices for everyone. 00:01:51.892 --> 00:01:55.068 Who would be made better off by the resulting single price? 00:01:55.450 --> 00:01:57.350 Well, Europeans are not better off 00:01:57.350 --> 00:01:59.361 because they're still paying a high price 00:01:59.361 --> 00:02:01.291 under the single price rule, 00:02:01.291 --> 00:02:03.231 but Africans are going to be worse off, 00:02:03.231 --> 00:02:05.281 because they will no longer have the option 00:02:05.281 --> 00:02:08.174 of buying important drugs at the lower prices. 00:02:08.880 --> 00:02:11.592 In this case, price discrimination is beneficial 00:02:11.592 --> 00:02:13.701 because it increases output. 00:02:13.701 --> 00:02:17.058 It gives some Africans the chance to buy at a lower price 00:02:17.058 --> 00:02:19.390 when they otherwise would not have had that chance 00:02:19.390 --> 00:02:21.964 under a no price discrimination rule. 00:02:22.461 --> 00:02:24.662 For industries with high fixed costs, 00:02:24.662 --> 00:02:26.873 price discrimination has another benefit -- 00:02:27.334 --> 00:02:30.615 the extra profits generated by price discrimination 00:02:30.615 --> 00:02:32.851 mean that it's more profitable for the company 00:02:32.851 --> 00:02:35.270 to engage in research and development 00:02:35.270 --> 00:02:37.534 to produce more new drugs for instance. 00:02:38.000 --> 00:02:41.330 For example, the extra profits from selling in Africa 00:02:41.330 --> 00:02:44.260 mean that research and development is more profitable, 00:02:44.260 --> 00:02:46.370 and that benefits Europeans too. 00:02:46.672 --> 00:02:48.145 When it comes to new drugs, 00:02:48.145 --> 00:02:50.487 you might say that misery loves company. 00:02:50.771 --> 00:02:53.562 That is, the larger the market for a potential drug, 00:02:53.562 --> 00:02:56.268 the more research and development will be applied. 00:02:56.797 --> 00:03:00.381 Price discrimination similarly means airlines can offer 00:03:00.381 --> 00:03:03.262 more flights to more places at better times, 00:03:03.262 --> 00:03:05.632 and that also helps business people. 00:03:05.632 --> 00:03:07.682 Even though they're paying the higher prices, 00:03:07.682 --> 00:03:09.928 they have a better chance at being able to get there 00:03:09.928 --> 00:03:12.121 at a good time in the first place. 00:03:12.808 --> 00:03:15.681 When it comes to software, lower prices for the students 00:03:15.681 --> 00:03:19.303 also is going to help support software R&D. 00:03:19.709 --> 00:03:22.423 If the students wouldn't buy the software at all 00:03:22.423 --> 00:03:25.443 at the higher price, well then the price discrimination 00:03:25.443 --> 00:03:27.955 is a net benefit to pretty much everyone. 00:03:28.323 --> 00:03:31.921 More generally, price discrimination can help spread the fixed costs 00:03:31.921 --> 00:03:35.603 of research and development over a larger population, 00:03:35.603 --> 00:03:37.123 and that means more innovation 00:03:37.123 --> 00:03:39.703 which is to virtually everyone's benefit. 00:03:40.113 --> 00:03:42.474 The ultimate form of price discrimination 00:03:42.474 --> 00:03:44.409 is when each person is charged 00:03:44.409 --> 00:03:46.740 his or her maximum willingness to pay. 00:03:47.041 --> 00:03:50.573 Economists call this “perfect price discrimination.” 00:03:50.573 --> 00:03:52.572 Under perfect price discrimination, 00:03:52.572 --> 00:03:55.773 consumers end up with zero consumer surplus. 00:03:56.185 --> 00:03:58.844 All of the gains from trade go to the monopolist, 00:03:58.844 --> 00:04:00.974 but the efficient quantity is produced. 00:04:00.974 --> 00:04:02.813 There's no deadweight loss. 00:04:03.284 --> 00:04:05.374 Let's look at this with a diagram. 00:04:05.374 --> 00:04:08.949 Think of the demand curve as showing the maximum willingness to pay 00:04:08.949 --> 00:04:12.995 by different individuals to buy a single unit of this good. 00:04:13.605 --> 00:04:16.844 Here, for example, is Alex's willingness to pay. 00:04:16.844 --> 00:04:20.443 Here's Tyler's willingness to pay, Robin's, and on, 00:04:20.443 --> 00:04:23.734 all the way down to Brian's willingness to pay for the good. 00:04:24.264 --> 00:04:27.536 If the monopolist could charge each and every consumer 00:04:27.536 --> 00:04:29.633 his or her maximum willingness to pay, 00:04:29.633 --> 00:04:32.513 the monopolist would walk down the demand curve 00:04:32.513 --> 00:04:35.984 producing each unit such that the willingness to pay 00:04:35.984 --> 00:04:37.924 just exceeded the marginal cost. 00:04:38.773 --> 00:04:41.911 In other words, the monopolist would produce every unit 00:04:41.911 --> 00:04:44.821 up until the efficient quantity of output, 00:04:44.821 --> 00:04:48.352 the same quantity as would be produced by a competitive industry. 00:04:48.352 --> 00:04:51.561 The difference being that in the competitive industry, 00:04:51.561 --> 00:04:53.882 the gains would go to the consumers. 00:04:54.426 --> 00:04:56.751 In the case of perfect price discrimination, 00:04:56.751 --> 00:04:58.909 all the gains go to the monopolist. 00:04:59.195 --> 00:05:02.592 This kind of price discrimination requires that the monopolist 00:05:02.592 --> 00:05:05.181 have a lot of information about each consumer. 00:05:05.766 --> 00:05:08.138 Are there examples of this in practice? 00:05:08.362 --> 00:05:09.734 In fact there are some, 00:05:09.992 --> 00:05:12.471 and you may be very familiar with one of them. 00:05:12.921 --> 00:05:16.050 Universities are fabulous price discriminators. 00:05:16.050 --> 00:05:17.933 They're even better than the airlines, 00:05:17.933 --> 00:05:21.759 especially because few people realize what is actually going on. 00:05:22.187 --> 00:05:25.374 Universities give many students financial aid, 00:05:25.374 --> 00:05:27.343 which is another way of saying that they charge 00:05:27.343 --> 00:05:29.602 some of their students more than others. 00:05:30.062 --> 00:05:33.133 Financial aid is a way of doing well while doing good 00:05:33.133 --> 00:05:35.673 because it's a form of price discrimination. 00:05:35.673 --> 00:05:38.141 It increases profits for universities. 00:05:38.443 --> 00:05:39.943 Moreover, to get the aid, 00:05:39.943 --> 00:05:42.712 students and their parents must give the university 00:05:42.712 --> 00:05:45.433 an incredible amount of financial information, 00:05:45.433 --> 00:05:48.552 including their tax forms, their W2's, 00:05:48.552 --> 00:05:50.563 information about their bank accounts, 00:05:50.563 --> 00:05:52.405 the home they own and so on. 00:05:52.853 --> 00:05:56.313 All of this information means the universities can create 00:05:56.313 --> 00:05:58.042 many, many different prices 00:05:58.042 --> 00:06:01.315 in a way that approaches perfect price discrimination. 00:06:01.653 --> 00:06:03.633 At Williams College for instance, 00:06:03.633 --> 00:06:05.872 half the students pay full fare, 00:06:05.872 --> 00:06:08.744 which is about $32,000 a year. 00:06:08.744 --> 00:06:11.374 The other half gets some form of financial aid, 00:06:11.374 --> 00:06:13.529 but the amount varies tremendously. 00:06:14.032 --> 00:06:19.224 Students whose parents have incomes of about $91,000 a year or higher, 00:06:19.224 --> 00:06:23.625 they pay an average in tuition of about $22,000 a year. 00:06:23.625 --> 00:06:25.904 While students from very poor families 00:06:25.904 --> 00:06:29.563 may pay as little as $1,600 a year. 00:06:29.804 --> 00:06:31.243 That's meaning that one price can be 00:06:31.243 --> 00:06:33.984 about 20 times higher than the other. 00:06:33.984 --> 00:06:36.038 That's a lot of price discrimination. 00:06:36.540 --> 00:06:39.734 Price discrimination makes a lot of sense for universities 00:06:39.734 --> 00:06:41.731 because their marginal costs are low 00:06:41.731 --> 00:06:43.816 while their fixed costs are pretty high. 00:06:44.126 --> 00:06:47.705 If a professor is teaching Economics 101 anyway, 00:06:47.705 --> 00:06:51.104 then the marginal cost of putting an extra student in the classroom 00:06:51.104 --> 00:06:52.837 is pretty close to zero. 00:06:53.130 --> 00:06:56.735 Even a student who is paying a smaller amount in tuition 00:06:56.735 --> 00:06:59.779 is probably adding more to profits than to costs. 00:07:00.040 --> 00:07:03.205 That helps the university cover its fixed costs 00:07:03.205 --> 00:07:05.464 such as the salaries and the buildings 00:07:05.464 --> 00:07:08.920 necessary to support the operations of the university. 00:07:09.508 --> 00:07:12.525 So again, price discrimination by the universities 00:07:12.525 --> 00:07:14.196 increases profits, 00:07:14.196 --> 00:07:17.504 but it also probably increases their output as well. 00:07:17.504 --> 00:07:21.685 More students attend university than otherwise would be the case. 00:07:21.685 --> 00:07:25.721 And again, price discrimination also helps to spread the fixed costs 00:07:25.721 --> 00:07:28.306 around a larger number of customers. 00:07:28.561 --> 00:07:31.965 For these reasons, price discrimination by universities 00:07:31.965 --> 00:07:34.656 probably increases social welfare. 00:07:35.045 --> 00:07:38.556 That's it for the more obvious forms of price discrimination. 00:07:38.556 --> 00:07:40.257 In the next talk we'll be looking 00:07:40.257 --> 00:07:42.784 at some quite common pricing strategies, 00:07:42.784 --> 00:07:44.466 such as tying and bundling, 00:07:44.466 --> 00:07:46.127 which also can be understood 00:07:46.127 --> 00:07:49.306 as more subtle forms of price discrimination. 00:07:51.074 --> 00:07:52.687 - [Announcer] If you want to test yourself, 00:07:52.687 --> 00:07:54.197 click “Practice Questions.” 00:07:55.018 --> 00:07:58.271 Or, if you're ready to move on, just click “Next Video.” 00:07:58.497 --> 00:08:02.396 ♪ [music] ♪