1 00:00:00,153 --> 00:00:05,716 ♪ [music] ♪ 2 00:00:09,468 --> 00:00:10,638 - [Tyler] In our last video, 3 00:00:10,638 --> 00:00:13,798 we saw that price discrimination is good for the monopolist. 4 00:00:13,798 --> 00:00:15,227 It increases profits, 5 00:00:15,227 --> 00:00:17,512 but what about for society as a whole, 6 00:00:17,512 --> 00:00:20,638 does price discrimination increase social welfare? 7 00:00:20,638 --> 00:00:22,557 That's the topic of today's talk. 8 00:00:27,769 --> 00:00:30,294 It's complicated, but here's a rule of thumb -- 9 00:00:30,294 --> 00:00:32,908 if price discrimination increases output 10 00:00:32,908 --> 00:00:35,186 then it's very likely to be beneficial, 11 00:00:35,186 --> 00:00:37,059 to increase social welfare. 12 00:00:37,059 --> 00:00:39,169 If output, however, does not increase 13 00:00:39,169 --> 00:00:41,688 then welfare probably is reduced. 14 00:00:41,688 --> 00:00:42,969 Let's give some intuition 15 00:00:42,969 --> 00:00:46,098 for when price discrimination increases welfare. 16 00:00:46,098 --> 00:00:47,798 Think about our previous example 17 00:00:47,798 --> 00:00:50,638 of the pharmaceutical company GSK 18 00:00:50,638 --> 00:00:52,599 setting a high drug price in Europe 19 00:00:52,599 --> 00:00:54,888 and a lower drug price in Africa. 20 00:00:54,888 --> 00:00:58,554 Suppose that GSK were forced to charge only one price. 21 00:00:58,983 --> 00:01:02,019 Do you think it would charge closer to the European price 22 00:01:02,019 --> 00:01:04,290 of $12.50 per pill 23 00:01:04,290 --> 00:01:07,681 or closer to the African price of 50 cents per pill? 24 00:01:08,124 --> 00:01:09,759 What's more likely to happen 25 00:01:09,759 --> 00:01:12,938 if GSK is required to set only one price? 26 00:01:13,440 --> 00:01:15,381 If they can't price discriminate, 27 00:01:15,381 --> 00:01:19,509 GSK very likely will simply abandon the African market 28 00:01:19,509 --> 00:01:22,101 where they weren't making that much profit anyway 29 00:01:22,101 --> 00:01:24,009 and set a single world price 30 00:01:24,009 --> 00:01:26,219 pretty close to the European level. 31 00:01:26,707 --> 00:01:29,801 People sometimes think that if only everyone were allowed 32 00:01:29,801 --> 00:01:33,048 to import pharmaceuticals to the United States 33 00:01:33,048 --> 00:01:36,200 from Canada, Mexico, or Africa where they're cheaper, 34 00:01:36,200 --> 00:01:38,441 then we would all enjoy lower prices. 35 00:01:38,902 --> 00:01:40,038 Probably not. 36 00:01:40,200 --> 00:01:43,451 If smuggling or legal re-importation of pharmaceuticals 37 00:01:43,451 --> 00:01:44,969 were to become more common, 38 00:01:44,969 --> 00:01:48,726 then pharmaceutical companies would stop price discriminating 39 00:01:48,726 --> 00:01:50,934 and set higher prices for everyone. 40 00:01:51,892 --> 00:01:55,068 Who would be made better off by the resulting single price? 41 00:01:55,450 --> 00:01:57,350 Well, Europeans are not better off 42 00:01:57,350 --> 00:01:59,361 because they're still paying a high price 43 00:01:59,361 --> 00:02:01,291 under the single price rule, 44 00:02:01,291 --> 00:02:03,231 but Africans are going to be worse off, 45 00:02:03,231 --> 00:02:05,281 because they will no longer have the option 46 00:02:05,281 --> 00:02:08,174 of buying important drugs at the lower prices. 47 00:02:08,880 --> 00:02:11,592 In this case, price discrimination is beneficial 48 00:02:11,592 --> 00:02:13,701 because it increases output. 49 00:02:13,701 --> 00:02:17,058 It gives some Africans the chance to buy at a lower price 50 00:02:17,058 --> 00:02:19,390 when they otherwise would not have had that chance 51 00:02:19,390 --> 00:02:21,964 under a no price discrimination rule. 52 00:02:22,461 --> 00:02:24,662 For industries with high fixed costs, 53 00:02:24,662 --> 00:02:26,873 price discrimination has another benefit -- 54 00:02:27,334 --> 00:02:30,615 the extra profits generated by price discrimination 55 00:02:30,615 --> 00:02:32,851 mean that it's more profitable for the company 56 00:02:32,851 --> 00:02:35,270 to engage in research and development 57 00:02:35,270 --> 00:02:37,534 to produce more new drugs for instance. 58 00:02:38,000 --> 00:02:41,330 For example, the extra profits from selling in Africa 59 00:02:41,330 --> 00:02:44,260 mean that research and development is more profitable, 60 00:02:44,260 --> 00:02:46,370 and that benefits Europeans too. 61 00:02:46,672 --> 00:02:48,145 When it comes to new drugs, 62 00:02:48,145 --> 00:02:50,487 you might say that misery loves company. 63 00:02:50,771 --> 00:02:53,562 That is, the larger the market for a potential drug, 64 00:02:53,562 --> 00:02:56,268 the more research and development will be applied. 65 00:02:56,797 --> 00:03:00,381 Price discrimination similarly means airlines can offer 66 00:03:00,381 --> 00:03:03,262 more flights to more places at better times, 67 00:03:03,262 --> 00:03:05,632 and that also helps business people. 68 00:03:05,632 --> 00:03:07,682 Even though they're paying the higher prices, 69 00:03:07,682 --> 00:03:09,928 they have a better chance at being able to get there 70 00:03:09,928 --> 00:03:12,121 at a good time in the first place. 71 00:03:12,808 --> 00:03:15,681 When it comes to software, lower prices for the students 72 00:03:15,681 --> 00:03:19,303 also is going to help support software R&D. 73 00:03:19,709 --> 00:03:22,423 If the students wouldn't buy the software at all 74 00:03:22,423 --> 00:03:25,443 at the higher price, well then the price discrimination 75 00:03:25,443 --> 00:03:27,955 is a net benefit to pretty much everyone. 76 00:03:28,323 --> 00:03:31,921 More generally, price discrimination can help spread the fixed costs 77 00:03:31,921 --> 00:03:35,603 of research and development over a larger population, 78 00:03:35,603 --> 00:03:37,123 and that means more innovation 79 00:03:37,123 --> 00:03:39,703 which is to virtually everyone's benefit. 80 00:03:40,113 --> 00:03:42,474 The ultimate form of price discrimination 81 00:03:42,474 --> 00:03:44,409 is when each person is charged 82 00:03:44,409 --> 00:03:46,740 his or her maximum willingness to pay. 83 00:03:47,041 --> 00:03:50,573 Economists call this “perfect price discrimination.” 84 00:03:50,573 --> 00:03:52,572 Under perfect price discrimination, 85 00:03:52,572 --> 00:03:55,773 consumers end up with zero consumer surplus. 86 00:03:56,185 --> 00:03:58,844 All of the gains from trade go to the monopolist, 87 00:03:58,844 --> 00:04:00,974 but the efficient quantity is produced. 88 00:04:00,974 --> 00:04:02,813 There's no deadweight loss. 89 00:04:03,284 --> 00:04:05,374 Let's look at this with a diagram. 90 00:04:05,374 --> 00:04:08,949 Think of the demand curve as showing the maximum willingness to pay 91 00:04:08,949 --> 00:04:12,995 by different individuals to buy a single unit of this good. 92 00:04:13,605 --> 00:04:16,844 Here, for example, is Alex's willingness to pay. 93 00:04:16,844 --> 00:04:20,443 Here's Tyler's willingness to pay, Robin's, and on, 94 00:04:20,443 --> 00:04:23,734 all the way down to Brian's willingness to pay for the good. 95 00:04:24,264 --> 00:04:27,536 If the monopolist could charge each and every consumer 96 00:04:27,536 --> 00:04:29,633 his or her maximum willingness to pay, 97 00:04:29,633 --> 00:04:32,513 the monopolist would walk down the demand curve 98 00:04:32,513 --> 00:04:35,984 producing each unit such that the willingness to pay 99 00:04:35,984 --> 00:04:37,924 just exceeded the marginal cost. 100 00:04:38,773 --> 00:04:41,911 In other words, the monopolist would produce every unit 101 00:04:41,911 --> 00:04:44,821 up until the efficient quantity of output, 102 00:04:44,821 --> 00:04:48,352 the same quantity as would be produced by a competitive industry. 103 00:04:48,352 --> 00:04:51,561 The difference being that in the competitive industry, 104 00:04:51,561 --> 00:04:53,882 the gains would go to the consumers. 105 00:04:54,426 --> 00:04:56,751 In the case of perfect price discrimination, 106 00:04:56,751 --> 00:04:58,909 all the gains go to the monopolist. 107 00:04:59,195 --> 00:05:02,592 This kind of price discrimination requires that the monopolist 108 00:05:02,592 --> 00:05:05,181 have a lot of information about each consumer. 109 00:05:05,766 --> 00:05:08,138 Are there examples of this in practice? 110 00:05:08,362 --> 00:05:09,734 In fact there are some, 111 00:05:09,992 --> 00:05:12,471 and you may be very familiar with one of them. 112 00:05:12,921 --> 00:05:16,050 Universities are fabulous price discriminators. 113 00:05:16,050 --> 00:05:17,933 They're even better than the airlines, 114 00:05:17,933 --> 00:05:21,759 especially because few people realize what is actually going on. 115 00:05:22,187 --> 00:05:25,374 Universities give many students financial aid, 116 00:05:25,374 --> 00:05:27,343 which is another way of saying that they charge 117 00:05:27,343 --> 00:05:29,602 some of their students more than others. 118 00:05:30,062 --> 00:05:33,133 Financial aid is a way of doing well while doing good 119 00:05:33,133 --> 00:05:35,673 because it's a form of price discrimination. 120 00:05:35,673 --> 00:05:38,141 It increases profits for universities. 121 00:05:38,443 --> 00:05:39,943 Moreover, to get the aid, 122 00:05:39,943 --> 00:05:42,712 students and their parents must give the university 123 00:05:42,712 --> 00:05:45,433 an incredible amount of financial information, 124 00:05:45,433 --> 00:05:48,552 including their tax forms, their W2's, 125 00:05:48,552 --> 00:05:50,563 information about their bank accounts, 126 00:05:50,563 --> 00:05:52,405 the home they own and so on. 127 00:05:52,853 --> 00:05:56,313 All of this information means the universities can create 128 00:05:56,313 --> 00:05:58,042 many, many different prices 129 00:05:58,042 --> 00:06:01,315 in a way that approaches perfect price discrimination. 130 00:06:01,653 --> 00:06:03,633 At Williams College for instance, 131 00:06:03,633 --> 00:06:05,872 half the students pay full fare, 132 00:06:05,872 --> 00:06:08,744 which is about $32,000 a year. 133 00:06:08,744 --> 00:06:11,374 The other half gets some form of financial aid, 134 00:06:11,374 --> 00:06:13,529 but the amount varies tremendously. 135 00:06:14,032 --> 00:06:19,224 Students whose parents have incomes of about $91,000 a year or higher, 136 00:06:19,224 --> 00:06:23,625 they pay an average in tuition of about $22,000 a year. 137 00:06:23,625 --> 00:06:25,904 While students from very poor families 138 00:06:25,904 --> 00:06:29,563 may pay as little as $1,600 a year. 139 00:06:29,804 --> 00:06:31,243 That's meaning that one price can be 140 00:06:31,243 --> 00:06:33,984 about 20 times higher than the other. 141 00:06:33,984 --> 00:06:36,038 That's a lot of price discrimination. 142 00:06:36,540 --> 00:06:39,734 Price discrimination makes a lot of sense for universities 143 00:06:39,734 --> 00:06:41,731 because their marginal costs are low 144 00:06:41,731 --> 00:06:43,816 while their fixed costs are pretty high. 145 00:06:44,126 --> 00:06:47,705 If a professor is teaching Economics 101 anyway, 146 00:06:47,705 --> 00:06:51,104 then the marginal cost of putting an extra student in the classroom 147 00:06:51,104 --> 00:06:52,837 is pretty close to zero. 148 00:06:53,130 --> 00:06:56,735 Even a student who is paying a smaller amount in tuition 149 00:06:56,735 --> 00:06:59,779 is probably adding more to profits than to costs. 150 00:07:00,040 --> 00:07:03,205 That helps the university cover its fixed costs 151 00:07:03,205 --> 00:07:05,464 such as the salaries and the buildings 152 00:07:05,464 --> 00:07:08,920 necessary to support the operations of the university. 153 00:07:09,508 --> 00:07:12,525 So again, price discrimination by the universities 154 00:07:12,525 --> 00:07:14,196 increases profits, 155 00:07:14,196 --> 00:07:17,504 but it also probably increases their output as well. 156 00:07:17,504 --> 00:07:21,685 More students attend university than otherwise would be the case. 157 00:07:21,685 --> 00:07:25,721 And again, price discrimination also helps to spread the fixed costs 158 00:07:25,721 --> 00:07:28,306 around a larger number of customers. 159 00:07:28,561 --> 00:07:31,965 For these reasons, price discrimination by universities 160 00:07:31,965 --> 00:07:34,656 probably increases social welfare. 161 00:07:35,045 --> 00:07:38,556 That's it for the more obvious forms of price discrimination. 162 00:07:38,556 --> 00:07:40,257 In the next talk we'll be looking 163 00:07:40,257 --> 00:07:42,784 at some quite common pricing strategies, 164 00:07:42,784 --> 00:07:44,466 such as tying and bundling, 165 00:07:44,466 --> 00:07:46,127 which also can be understood 166 00:07:46,127 --> 00:07:49,306 as more subtle forms of price discrimination. 167 00:07:51,074 --> 00:07:52,687 - [Announcer] If you want to test yourself, 168 00:07:52,687 --> 00:07:54,197 click “Practice Questions.” 169 00:07:55,018 --> 00:07:58,271 Or, if you're ready to move on, just click “Next Video.” 170 00:07:58,497 --> 00:08:02,396 ♪ [music] ♪