0:00:01.920,0:00:04.699 ♪ [music] ♪ 0:00:09.370,0:00:10.960 - [Tyler] In our last video, 0:00:10.960,0:00:13.960 we saw that price discrimination[br]is good for the monopolist. 0:00:13.960,0:00:15.110 It increases profits, 0:00:15.110,0:00:18.110 but what about [br]for society as a whole, 0:00:18.110,0:00:24.359 does price discrimination[br]increase social welfare? 0:00:24.359,0:00:27.359 That's the topic of today's talk. 0:00:28.030,0:00:29.320 It's complicated, but here's[br]a rule of thumb -- 0:00:29.320,0:00:32.320 if price discrimination[br]increases output 0:00:32.320,0:00:34.420 then it's very likely[br]to be beneficial, 0:00:34.420,0:00:37.420 to increase social welfare. 0:00:37.420,0:00:39.180 If output, however,[br]does not increase 0:00:39.180,0:00:42.180 then welfare probably is reduced. 0:00:42.180,0:00:43.480 Let's give some intuition 0:00:43.480,0:00:46.480 for when price discrimination[br]increases welfare. 0:00:46.480,0:00:48.440 Think about our previous example 0:00:48.440,0:00:51.440 of the pharmaceutical company GSK 0:00:51.440,0:00:53.480 setting a high drug price in Europe 0:00:53.480,0:00:56.480 and a lower drug price in Africa. 0:00:56.480,0:00:57.920 Suppose that GSK were forced[br]to charge only one price. 0:00:57.920,0:01:00.920 Do you think it would charge 0:01:00.920,0:01:04.090 closer to the European price[br]of $12.50 per pill 0:01:04.090,0:01:07.090 or closer to the African price[br]of 50 cents per pill? 0:01:07.090,0:01:10.770 What's more likely to happen 0:01:10.770,0:01:13.770 if GSK is required[br]to set only one price? 0:01:13.770,0:01:15.900 If they can't price discriminate, 0:01:15.900,0:01:18.900 GSK very likely will simply abandon[br]the African market 0:01:18.900,0:01:21.230 where they weren't making[br]that much profit anyway 0:01:21.230,0:01:24.230 and set a single world price 0:01:24.230,0:01:26.590 pretty close to the European level. 0:01:26.590,0:01:29.590 People sometimes think that[br]if only everyone were allowed 0:01:29.590,0:01:34.580 to import pharmaceuticals[br]to the United States from Canada, 0:01:34.760,0:01:37.410 Mexico or Africa[br]where they're cheaper, 0:01:37.410,0:01:38.410 then we would all enjoy[br]lower prices. 0:01:38.410,0:01:40.410 Probably not. 0:01:40.410,0:01:42.210 Smuggling or illegal re-importation[br]of pharmaceuticals 0:01:42.210,0:01:45.210 were to become more common, 0:01:45.210,0:01:49.820 then pharmaceutical companies[br]would stop price discriminating 0:01:50.000,0:01:53.130 and set higher prices for everyone. 0:01:53.130,0:01:56.130 Who would be made better off[br]by the resulting single price? 0:01:56.130,0:01:57.130 Well, Europeans are not better off 0:01:57.130,0:01:59.770 because they're still paying[br]a high price 0:01:59.770,0:02:00.770 under the single price rule, 0:02:00.770,0:02:03.430 but Africans are going[br]to be worse off, 0:02:03.430,0:02:04.430 because they will no longer[br]have the option 0:02:04.430,0:02:07.060 of buying important drugs[br]at the lower prices. 0:02:07.060,0:02:12.050 In this case,[br]price discrimination is beneficial 0:02:12.230,0:02:14.410 because it increases output. 0:02:14.410,0:02:17.410 It gives some Africans[br]the chance to buy at a lower price 0:02:17.410,0:02:21.030 when they otherwise would not[br]have had that chance 0:02:21.210,0:02:24.400 under a no price discrimination rule. 0:02:24.400,0:02:25.400 For industries[br]with high fixed costs, 0:02:25.400,0:02:27.400 price discrimination[br]has another benefit - 0:02:27.400,0:02:31.330 the extra profits generated[br]by price discrimination mean 0:02:31.510,0:02:33.130 that it's more profitable[br]for the company 0:02:33.130,0:02:36.130 to engage in research[br]and development 0:02:36.130,0:02:38.700 to produce more new drugs[br]for instance. 0:02:38.700,0:02:41.700 For example, the extra profits[br]from selling in Africa 0:02:41.700,0:02:45.610 mean that research and development[br]is more profitable, 0:02:45.790,0:02:48.460 and that benefits Europeans too. 0:02:48.460,0:02:49.460 When it comes to new drugs, 0:02:49.460,0:02:51.460 you might say that misery[br]loves company. 0:02:51.460,0:02:52.530 That is, the larger the market[br]for a potential drug, 0:02:52.530,0:02:55.530 the more research[br]and development will be applied. 0:02:55.530,0:03:01.210 Price discrimination similarly[br]means airlines can offer 0:03:01.390,0:03:03.260 more flights to more places[br]at better times, 0:03:03.260,0:03:04.260 and that also helps business people. 0:03:04.260,0:03:06.260 Even though they're paying[br]the higher prices, 0:03:06.260,0:03:09.760 they have a better chance[br]at being able to get there 0:03:09.940,0:03:15.040 at a good time in the first place. 0:03:15.220,0:03:17.990 When it comes to software,[br]lower prices for the students 0:03:17.990,0:03:20.990 also is going to help[br]support software R&D. 0:03:20.990,0:03:22.660 If the students wouldn't buy[br]the software at all 0:03:22.660,0:03:25.660 at the higher price,[br]well then the price discrimination 0:03:25.660,0:03:27.630 is a net benefit[br]to pretty much everyone. 0:03:27.630,0:03:30.630 More generally, price discrimination[br]can help spread the fixed costs 0:03:30.630,0:03:35.550 of research and development[br]over a larger population, 0:03:35.730,0:03:37.770 and that means more innovation 0:03:37.770,0:03:40.770 which is to virtually[br]everyone's benefit. 0:03:40.770,0:03:42.610 The ultimate form[br]of price discrimination 0:03:42.610,0:03:45.610 is when each person is charged 0:03:45.610,0:03:48.020 his or her maximum[br]willingness to pay. 0:03:48.020,0:03:51.020 Economists call this[br]“perfect price discrimination.” 0:03:51.020,0:03:53.720 Under perfect price discrimination, 0:03:53.720,0:03:56.720 consumers end up[br]with zero consumers surplus. 0:03:56.720,0:03:58.160 All of the gains from trade[br]go to the monopolist, 0:03:58.160,0:04:01.160 but the efficient quantity[br]is produced. 0:04:01.160,0:04:03.280 There's no deadweight loss. 0:04:03.280,0:04:06.280 Let's look at this with a diagram. 0:04:06.280,0:04:08.020 Think of the demand curve as showing[br]the maximum willingness to pay 0:04:08.020,0:04:11.020 by different individuals to buy[br]a single unit of this good. 0:04:11.020,0:04:17.029 Here, for example,[br]is Alex's willingness to pay. 0:04:17.209,0:04:19.500 Here's Tyler's willingness to pay,[br]Robin's, and on, 0:04:19.500,0:04:22.500 all the way down to Brian's[br]willingness to pay for the good. 0:04:22.500,0:04:27.890 If the monopolist could charge[br]each and every consumer 0:04:28.070,0:04:30.200 his or her maximum[br]willingness to pay, 0:04:30.200,0:04:33.200 the monopolist would walk[br]down the demand curve 0:04:33.200,0:04:36.160 producing each unit such[br]that the willingness to pay 0:04:36.160,0:04:39.160 just exceeded the marginal cost. 0:04:39.160,0:04:41.070 In other words, the monopolist[br]would produce every unit 0:04:41.070,0:04:44.070 up until the efficient[br]quantity of output, 0:04:44.070,0:04:48.680 the same quantity as would be[br]produced by a competitive industry. 0:04:48.860,0:04:52.730 The difference being that[br]in the competitive industry, 0:04:52.910,0:04:54.970 the gains would go[br]to the consumers. 0:04:54.970,0:04:57.970 In the case of[br]perfect price discrimination, 0:04:57.970,0:04:58.970 all the gains go to the monopolist. 0:04:58.970,0:05:01.850 This kind of price discrimination[br]requires that the monopolist have 0:05:01.850,0:05:07.080 a lot of information[br]about each consumer. 0:05:07.260,0:05:10.030 Are there examples[br]of this in practice? 0:05:10.030,0:05:11.030 In fact there are some, 0:05:11.030,0:05:13.030 and you may be very familiar[br]with one of them. 0:05:13.030,0:05:16.840 Universities are fabulous[br]price discriminators. 0:05:17.020,0:05:19.330 They're even better than the airlines, 0:05:19.330,0:05:22.330 especially because few people[br]realize what is actually going on. 0:05:22.330,0:05:24.060 Universities give many students[br]financial aid, 0:05:24.060,0:05:27.060 which is another way[br]of saying that they charge[br] 0:05:27.060,0:05:31.360 some of their students[br]more than others. 0:05:31.540,0:05:33.450 Financial aid is a way[br]of doing well while doing good 0:05:33.450,0:05:36.450 because it's a form[br]of price discrimination. 0:05:36.450,0:05:38.780 It increases profits[br]for universities. 0:05:38.780,0:05:41.780 Moreover, to get the aid, 0:05:41.780,0:05:43.210 students and their parents[br]must give the university 0:05:43.210,0:05:46.210 an incredible amount[br]of financial information, 0:05:46.210,0:05:48.820 including their tax forms,[br]their W2's, 0:05:48.820,0:05:51.820 information[br]about their bank accounts, 0:05:51.820,0:05:54.110 the home they own and so on. 0:05:54.110,0:05:57.110 All of this information means [br]the universities can create 0:05:57.110,0:05:58.820 many, many different prices 0:05:58.820,0:06:01.820 in a way that approaches[br]perfect price discrimination. 0:06:01.820,0:06:03.640 At Williams College for instance, 0:06:03.640,0:06:06.640 half the students pay full fare, 0:06:06.640,0:06:09.030 which is about $32,000 a year. 0:06:09.030,0:06:12.030 The other half gets some form[br]of financial aid, 0:06:12.030,0:06:15.270 but the amount varies tremendously. 0:06:15.270,0:06:18.270 Students whose parents have incomes[br]of about $91,000 a year or higher, 0:06:18.270,0:06:23.940 they pay an average in tuition[br]of about $22,000 a year. 0:06:24.120,0:06:27.108 While students[br]from very poor families 0:06:27.108,0:06:30.108 may pay as little as $1,600 a year. 0:06:30.108,0:06:31.953 That's meaning[br]that one price can be 0:06:31.953,0:06:34.953 about 20 times higher[br]than the other. 0:06:34.953,0:06:35.953 That's a lot of price discrimination. 0:06:35.953,0:06:38.754 Price discrimination makes[br]a lot of sense for universities 0:06:38.754,0:06:43.033 because their marginal costs are low 0:06:43.033,0:06:45.493 while their fixed costs[br]are pretty high. 0:06:45.493,0:06:48.493 If a professor is teaching[br]Economics 101 anyway, 0:06:48.493,0:06:53.589 then the marginal cost of putting[br]an extra student in the classroom 0:06:53.589,0:06:55.729 is pretty close to zero. 0:06:55.729,0:06:56.729 Even a student who is paying[br]a smaller amount in tuition 0:06:56.729,0:06:58.729 is probably adding more[br]to profits than to costs. 0:06:58.729,0:07:04.533 That helps the university[br]cover its fixed costs 0:07:04.533,0:07:07.285 such as the salaries[br]and the buildings 0:07:07.285,0:07:10.285 necessary to support[br]the operations of the university. 0:07:10.285,0:07:12.446 So again, price discrimination[br]by the universities 0:07:12.446,0:07:13.446 increases profits, 0:07:13.446,0:07:15.446 but it also probably increases[br]their output as well. 0:07:15.446,0:07:20.518 More students attend university[br]than otherwise would be the case. 0:07:20.518,0:07:25.170 And again, price discrimination[br]also helps to spread the fixed costs 0:07:25.170,0:07:30.521 around a larger number[br]of customers. 0:07:30.521,0:07:35.776 For these reasons,[br]price discrimination by universities 0:07:35.776,0:07:36.874 probably increases social welfare. 0:07:36.874,0:07:39.874 That's it for the more obvious[br]forms of price discrimination. 0:07:39.874,0:07:41.325 In the next talk we'll be looking at 0:07:41.325,0:07:42.777 some quite common[br]pricing strategies, 0:07:42.777,0:07:44.229 such as tying and bundling, 0:07:44.229,0:07:48.175 which also can be understood 0:07:48.175,0:07:51.175 as more subtle forms[br]of price discrimination. 0:07:51.175,0:07:52.175 - [Announcer] If you want[br]to test yourself, 0:07:52.175,0:07:54.800 click “Practice Questions.” 0:07:54.800,0:07:58.368 Or, if you're ready to move on,[br]just click “Next Video.” 0:07:59.488,0:08:02.137 ♪ [music] ♪