1 00:00:01,920 --> 00:00:04,699 ♪ [music] ♪ 2 00:00:09,370 --> 00:00:13,780 - [Tyler] In our last video, we saw that price discrimination is good for the monopolist. 3 00:00:13,960 --> 00:00:17,930 It increases profits, but what about for society as a whole, does price 4 00:00:18,110 --> 00:00:24,359 discrimination increase social welfare? That's the topic of today's talk. 5 00:00:28,030 --> 00:00:32,140 It's complicated, but here's a rule of thumb - if price discrimination increases 6 00:00:32,320 --> 00:00:37,240 output then it's very likely to be beneficial, to increase social welfare. If 7 00:00:37,420 --> 00:00:42,000 output, however, does not increase then welfare probably is reduced. Let's give 8 00:00:42,180 --> 00:00:46,300 some intuition for when price discrimination increases welfare. Think 9 00:00:46,480 --> 00:00:51,260 about our previous example of the pharmaceutical company GSK setting a high 10 00:00:51,440 --> 00:00:56,300 drug price in Europe and a lower drug price in Africa. Suppose that GSK were 11 00:00:56,480 --> 00:01:00,740 forced to charge only one price. Do you think it would charge closer to the 12 00:01:00,920 --> 00:01:06,910 European price of $12.50 per pill or closer to the African price of 50 cents 13 00:01:07,090 --> 00:01:13,590 per pill? What's more likely to happen if GSK is required to set only one price? If 14 00:01:13,770 --> 00:01:18,720 they can't price discriminate, GSK very likely will simply abandon the African 15 00:01:18,900 --> 00:01:24,050 market where they weren't making that much profit anyway and set a single world price 16 00:01:24,230 --> 00:01:29,410 pretty close to the European level. People sometimes think that if only everyone were 17 00:01:29,590 --> 00:01:34,580 allowed to import pharmaceuticals to the United States from Canada, Mexico or 18 00:01:34,760 --> 00:01:40,230 Africa where they're cheaper, then we would all enjoy lower prices. Probably not. 19 00:01:40,410 --> 00:01:45,030 Smuggling or illegal re-importation of pharmaceuticals were to become more common, 20 00:01:45,210 --> 00:01:49,820 then pharmaceutical companies would stop price discriminating and set higher prices 21 00:01:50,000 --> 00:01:55,950 for everyone. Who would be made better off by the resulting single price? Well, 22 00:01:56,130 --> 00:01:59,590 Europeans are not better off because they're still paying a high price under 23 00:01:59,770 --> 00:02:03,250 the single price rule, but Africans are going to be worse off, 24 00:02:03,430 --> 00:02:06,880 because they will no longer have the option of buying important drugs at the 25 00:02:07,060 --> 00:02:12,050 lower prices. In this case, price discrimination is beneficial because it 26 00:02:12,230 --> 00:02:17,230 increases output. It gives some Africans the chance to buy at a lower price when 27 00:02:17,410 --> 00:02:21,030 they otherwise would not have had that chance under a no price discrimination 28 00:02:21,210 --> 00:02:27,220 rule. For industries with high fixed costs, price discrimination has another benefit - 29 00:02:27,400 --> 00:02:31,330 the extra profits generated by price discrimination mean that it's more 30 00:02:31,510 --> 00:02:35,950 profitable for the company to engage in research and development to produce more 31 00:02:36,130 --> 00:02:41,520 new drugs for instance. For example, the extra profits from selling in Africa mean 32 00:02:41,700 --> 00:02:45,610 that research and development is more profitable, and that benefits Europeans 33 00:02:45,790 --> 00:02:51,280 too. When it comes to new drugs, you might say that misery loves company. That is, the 34 00:02:51,460 --> 00:02:55,350 larger the market for a potential drug, the more research and development will be 35 00:02:55,530 --> 00:03:01,210 applied. Price discrimination similarly means airlines can offer more flights to 36 00:03:01,390 --> 00:03:06,080 more places at better times, and that also helps business people. Even though they're 37 00:03:06,260 --> 00:03:09,760 paying the higher prices, they have a better chance at being able to get there 38 00:03:09,940 --> 00:03:15,040 at a good time in the first place. When it comes to software, lower prices for the 39 00:03:15,220 --> 00:03:20,810 students also is going to help support software R&D. If the students wouldn't 40 00:03:20,990 --> 00:03:25,480 buy the software at all at the higher price, well then the price discrimination 41 00:03:25,660 --> 00:03:30,450 is a net benefit to pretty much everyone. More generally, price discrimination can 42 00:03:30,630 --> 00:03:35,550 help spread the fixed costs of research and development over a larger population, 43 00:03:35,730 --> 00:03:40,590 and that means more innovation which is to virtually everyone's benefit. The ultimate 44 00:03:40,770 --> 00:03:45,430 form of price discrimination is when each person is charged his or her maximum 45 00:03:45,610 --> 00:03:50,840 willingness to pay. Economists call this “perfect price discrimination.” Under 46 00:03:51,020 --> 00:03:56,540 perfect price discrimination, consumers end up with zero consumers surplus. All of the 47 00:03:56,720 --> 00:04:00,980 gains from trade go to the monopolist, but the efficient quantity is produced. 48 00:04:01,160 --> 00:04:06,100 There's no deadweight loss. Let's look at this with a diagram. Think of the demand 49 00:04:06,280 --> 00:04:10,840 curve as showing the maximum willingness to pay by different individuals to buy a 50 00:04:11,020 --> 00:04:17,029 single unit of this good. Here, for example, is Alex's willingness to pay. Here's 51 00:04:17,209 --> 00:04:22,320 Tyler's willingness to pay, Robin's, and on, all the way down to Brian's willingness to 52 00:04:22,500 --> 00:04:27,890 pay for the good. If the monopolist could charge each and every consumer his or her 53 00:04:28,070 --> 00:04:33,020 maximum willingness to pay, the monopolist would walk down the demand curve producing 54 00:04:33,200 --> 00:04:38,980 each unit such that the willingness to pay just exceeded the marginal cost. In other 55 00:04:39,160 --> 00:04:43,890 words, the monopolist would produce every unit up until the efficient quantity of 56 00:04:44,070 --> 00:04:48,680 output, the same quantity as would be produced by a competitive industry. The 57 00:04:48,860 --> 00:04:52,730 difference being that in the competitive industry, the gains would go to the 58 00:04:52,910 --> 00:04:57,790 consumers. In the case of perfect price discrimination, all the gains go to the 59 00:04:57,970 --> 00:05:01,670 monopolist. This kind of price discrimination requires that the 60 00:05:01,850 --> 00:05:07,080 monopolist have a lot of information about each consumer. Are there examples of this 61 00:05:07,260 --> 00:05:12,850 in practice? In fact there are some, and you may be very familiar with one of them. 62 00:05:13,030 --> 00:05:16,840 Universities are fabulous price discriminators. They're even better than the 63 00:05:17,020 --> 00:05:22,150 airlines, especially because few people realize what is actually going on. 64 00:05:22,330 --> 00:05:26,880 Universities give many students financial aid, which is another way of saying that 65 00:05:27,060 --> 00:05:31,360 they charge some of their students more than others. Financial aid is a way of 66 00:05:31,540 --> 00:05:36,270 doing well while doing good because it's a form of price discrimination. It increases 67 00:05:36,450 --> 00:05:41,600 profits for universities. Moreover, to get the aid, students and their parents must 68 00:05:41,780 --> 00:05:46,030 give the university an incredible amount of financial information, including their 69 00:05:46,210 --> 00:05:51,640 tax forms, their W2's, information about their bank accounts, the home they own and 70 00:05:51,820 --> 00:05:56,930 so on. All of this information means the universities can create many, many 71 00:05:57,110 --> 00:06:01,640 different prices in a way that approaches perfect price discrimination. 72 00:06:01,820 --> 00:06:06,460 At William's College for instance, half the students pay full fare, which is about 73 00:06:06,640 --> 00:06:11,850 $32,000 a year. The other half gets some form of financial aid, but the amount 74 00:06:12,030 --> 00:06:18,090 varies tremendously. Students whose parents have incomes of about $91,000 a 75 00:06:18,270 --> 00:06:23,940 year or higher, they pay an average in tuition of about $22,000 a year. While 76 00:06:24,120 --> 00:06:30,108 students from very poor families may pay as little as $1,600 a year. That's 77 00:06:30,108 --> 00:06:34,953 meaning that one price can be about 20 times higher than the other. That's a lot 78 00:06:34,953 --> 00:06:38,754 of price discrimination. Price discrimination makes a lot of sense for 79 00:06:38,754 --> 00:06:43,033 universities because their marginal costs are low while their fixed costs are pretty 80 00:06:43,033 --> 00:06:48,493 high. If a professor is teaching Economics 101 anyway, then the marginal 81 00:06:48,493 --> 00:06:53,589 cost of putting an extra student in the classroom is pretty close to zero. Even a 82 00:06:53,589 --> 00:06:58,729 student who is paying a smaller amount in tuition is probably adding more to profits 83 00:06:58,729 --> 00:07:04,533 than to costs. That helps the university cover its fixed costs such as the salaries 84 00:07:04,533 --> 00:07:10,285 and the buildings necessary to support the operations of the university. So again, 85 00:07:10,285 --> 00:07:15,446 price discrimination by the universities increases profits, but it also probably 86 00:07:15,446 --> 00:07:20,518 increases their output as well. More students attend university than otherwise 87 00:07:20,518 --> 00:07:25,170 would be the case. And again, price discrimination also helps to spread the 88 00:07:25,170 --> 00:07:30,521 fixed costs around a larger number of customers. For these reasons, price 89 00:07:30,521 --> 00:07:35,776 discrimination by universities probably increases social welfare. That's it for 90 00:07:35,776 --> 00:07:39,874 the more obvious forms of price discrimination. In the next talk we'll be 91 00:07:39,874 --> 00:07:44,229 looking at the some quite common pricing strategies, such as tying and bundling, 92 00:07:44,229 --> 00:07:49,373 which also can be understood as more subtle forms of price discrimination. 93 00:07:51,175 --> 00:07:54,665 - [Announcer] If you want to test yourself, click “Practice Questions.” 94 00:07:54,800 --> 00:07:58,368 Or, if you're ready to move on, just click “Next Video.” 95 00:07:59,488 --> 00:08:02,137 ♪ [music] ♪