WEBVTT 00:00:00.000 --> 00:00:05.599 ♪ [music] ♪ 00:00:09.212 --> 00:00:11.771 - [Tyler] In the last lecture, we showed that the legal incidence 00:00:11.771 --> 00:00:15.016 of a tax does not determine the economic incidence. 00:00:15.016 --> 00:00:16.434 In this lecture, we're going to talk 00:00:16.434 --> 00:00:20.695 about how the economic incidence of taxes actually is determined. 00:00:20.695 --> 00:00:22.754 Who bears the burden of a tax? 00:00:28.255 --> 00:00:31.831 Here is the rule for the economic incidence of a tax. 00:00:31.831 --> 00:00:34.395 The more elastic side of the market will pay 00:00:34.395 --> 00:00:37.886 a smaller share of the tax, a smaller burden. 00:00:37.886 --> 00:00:40.988 Similarly, the less elastic side of the market 00:00:40.988 --> 00:00:44.342 or rather the more inelastic side of the market will pay 00:00:44.342 --> 00:00:46.298 a greater share of the tax. 00:00:46.298 --> 00:00:49.797 So more elastic pays a smaller share, 00:00:49.797 --> 00:00:52.991 less elastic pays a greater share. 00:00:52.991 --> 00:00:55.332 I'm going to show you this in a couple of diagrams 00:00:55.332 --> 00:00:58.611 and then give you the intuition for why it's the case. 00:00:58.611 --> 00:01:00.701 Let's suppose we can't remember the rule. 00:01:00.701 --> 00:01:03.702 Is it the more elastic side which bears the smaller share 00:01:03.702 --> 00:01:06.073 of the tax or the greater share of the tax? 00:01:06.073 --> 00:01:09.205 Say we can't quite remember. Well, no problem. 00:01:09.205 --> 00:01:12.953 Let's just draw the diagram and read it off as it happens. 00:01:12.979 --> 00:01:15.002 For instance, let's draw a diagram 00:01:15.002 --> 00:01:17.473 which has a pretty elastic demand curve 00:01:17.473 --> 00:01:21.514 and relatively speaking a pretty inelastic supply curve. 00:01:21.514 --> 00:01:23.991 Here's the price when there's no tax. 00:01:23.991 --> 00:01:26.333 Now let's look at what happens when there is a tax 00:01:26.333 --> 00:01:28.472 and we'll use our wedge method. 00:01:28.472 --> 00:01:30.957 Here's the tax and the height of the wedge gives us 00:01:30.957 --> 00:01:32.826 the amount of the tax. 00:01:32.826 --> 00:01:34.071 What do we do? 00:01:34.071 --> 00:01:35.921 We drive this wedge into the diagram 00:01:35.921 --> 00:01:38.402 until the top of it hits the demand curve 00:01:38.402 --> 00:01:40.937 and the bottom of it hits the supply curve 00:01:40.937 --> 00:01:43.815 and then we just read the answer off our diagram. 00:01:43.815 --> 00:01:47.345 Point B, this tells us the price paid by the buyer. 00:01:47.345 --> 00:01:51.538 Point D, this tells us the price received by the seller. 00:01:51.538 --> 00:01:53.002 Let's compare. 00:01:53.002 --> 00:01:55.804 When there was no tax, the price paid by the buyer 00:01:55.804 --> 00:01:58.697 was at A, and with the tax the price to the buyer 00:01:58.697 --> 00:02:01.028 goes up a little bit to point B. 00:02:01.028 --> 00:02:03.719 The buyer isn't paying much of a higher price. 00:02:03.719 --> 00:02:06.993 On the other hand the seller is receiving a lot less. 00:02:06.993 --> 00:02:10.729 In this case, when demand is more elastic than supply, 00:02:10.729 --> 00:02:13.623 the demanders pay a smaller share of the tax 00:02:13.623 --> 00:02:16.397 and the suppliers pay a larger share. 00:02:16.397 --> 00:02:19.396 Therefore we can just read off the diagram what happens 00:02:19.396 --> 00:02:22.227 when demand is more elastic than supply. 00:02:22.539 --> 00:02:24.145 You don't have to remember the rule, 00:02:24.145 --> 00:02:26.567 you don't have to memorize it because I'm going to give you 00:02:26.567 --> 00:02:29.483 some intuition to make it easy in just a moment. 00:02:29.483 --> 00:02:32.690 You simply have to draw the diagram and be able to read 00:02:32.690 --> 00:02:34.624 the answer off the curves. 00:02:34.779 --> 00:02:36.434 Let's look at another case. 00:02:36.434 --> 00:02:38.466 In this case, we've drawn a supply curve 00:02:38.466 --> 00:02:41.028 which is very inelastic and a demand curve 00:02:41.028 --> 00:02:44.048 which is less elastic than the supply curve. 00:02:44.048 --> 00:02:46.338 Once again we're going to take our tax wedge, 00:02:46.338 --> 00:02:49.706 we're going to push it into the diagram and what happens? 00:02:49.706 --> 00:02:51.127 You can see it right here. 00:02:51.127 --> 00:02:53.288 We just have to read it off the diagram. 00:02:53.288 --> 00:02:56.422 Now we see that compared to when there was no tax, 00:02:56.422 --> 00:02:58.943 the price to the buyer has gone up a lot 00:02:58.943 --> 00:03:01.172 and the price to the sellers has gone down 00:03:01.172 --> 00:03:03.041 by just a little bit. 00:03:03.041 --> 00:03:05.533 When the supply is more elastic than demand, 00:03:05.533 --> 00:03:08.020 buyers pay the greater share of the tax, 00:03:08.020 --> 00:03:10.549 that is the price to the buyer goes up more 00:03:10.549 --> 00:03:13.070 than the price to the sellers goes down. 00:03:13.070 --> 00:03:15.651 The buyers pay more of the tax when the supply curve 00:03:15.651 --> 00:03:17.323 is more elastic. 00:03:17.323 --> 00:03:18.877 Let's give some intuition. 00:03:18.877 --> 00:03:21.794 You can always get the right answer by drawing the curves. 00:03:21.794 --> 00:03:24.828 And let's consider the intuition for why that's the case. 00:03:24.828 --> 00:03:27.759 So here's the intuition for remembering the rule. 00:03:27.759 --> 00:03:31.039 Think about elasticity as a kind of escape. 00:03:31.039 --> 00:03:34.001 The side of the market which is the more elastic 00:03:34.001 --> 00:03:36.489 can escape the tax more easily. 00:03:36.489 --> 00:03:40.327 Why does that makes sense? Remember what elastic demand means. 00:03:40.327 --> 00:03:42.657 It means that demanders have good substitutes 00:03:42.657 --> 00:03:46.130 for the taxed good and so they can escape the tax. 00:03:46.130 --> 00:03:48.502 When the tax is high, the demanders are going to say, 00:03:48.502 --> 00:03:50.926 "We're just going to go buy the substitutes. 00:03:50.926 --> 00:03:53.254 We have plenty of good substitutes." 00:03:53.254 --> 00:03:55.303 On the other hand, think about what it means 00:03:55.303 --> 00:03:57.320 when the demand is inelastic. 00:03:57.320 --> 00:03:59.616 It means that there are no good substitutes 00:03:59.616 --> 00:04:02.064 so it's hard to escape the tax. 00:04:02.064 --> 00:04:05.378 What about the supply side, elastic supply? 00:04:05.378 --> 00:04:07.908 Well, that means the resources which are used to produce 00:04:07.908 --> 00:04:10.206 the taxed good, they can easily be moved 00:04:10.206 --> 00:04:11.728 to other industries. 00:04:11.728 --> 00:04:14.020 The resources can move around easily. 00:04:14.020 --> 00:04:17.560 If you try to tax the industry a lot then the land, the capital, 00:04:17.560 --> 00:04:19.824 the workers in that industry which were used 00:04:19.824 --> 00:04:21.793 to produce the good, they're just going to flow 00:04:21.793 --> 00:04:24.418 to other industries and so the suppliers 00:04:24.418 --> 00:04:26.956 can relatively easily escape the tax. 00:04:27.718 --> 00:04:30.463 On the other hand, if supply is inelastic 00:04:30.463 --> 00:04:33.365 that means the resources used to produce this good, 00:04:33.365 --> 00:04:36.594 they really can only be used to produce this good. 00:04:36.594 --> 00:04:38.890 They're fixed, they're hard to move around, 00:04:38.890 --> 00:04:40.727 and those factors are not that useful 00:04:40.727 --> 00:04:43.474 for producing other goods, so that makes it difficult 00:04:43.474 --> 00:04:46.616 for the suppliers when the supply curve is inelastic. 00:04:46.637 --> 00:04:48.963 That means it's difficult for the suppliers 00:04:48.963 --> 00:04:50.842 to escape the tax. 00:04:51.051 --> 00:04:52.963 What if the demanders and the suppliers 00:04:52.963 --> 00:04:54.752 are both pretty elastic? 00:04:54.752 --> 00:04:55.984 Well, here's the thing. 00:04:55.984 --> 00:04:59.990 Somebody has to pay the tax, both sides can't escape the tax 00:04:59.990 --> 00:05:02.618 at least if the good is going to be bought and sold, 00:05:02.618 --> 00:05:07.296 therefore the burden is determined by the relative elasticities. 00:05:07.296 --> 00:05:11.308 It's about which side has it easier to escape the tax 00:05:11.308 --> 00:05:13.547 and that side will pay less of the tax. 00:05:13.547 --> 00:05:16.508 The side which is less elastic, they're going to pay 00:05:16.508 --> 00:05:19.581 more of the tax because that side finds it harder 00:05:19.581 --> 00:05:21.690 to escape the tax. 00:05:21.690 --> 00:05:25.521 So let's do an application, say social security taxes. 00:05:25.881 --> 00:05:28.619 Last time we showed that the legal incidence 00:05:28.619 --> 00:05:31.346 of social security taxes has no bearing 00:05:31.346 --> 00:05:33.903 on the economic incidence, but we didn't say 00:05:33.903 --> 00:05:36.445 what the economic incidence actually is. 00:05:36.445 --> 00:05:38.268 So let's do that now. 00:05:38.268 --> 00:05:41.159 We're going to have the price of labor up here, the wage, 00:05:41.159 --> 00:05:43.712 and the quantity of labor down here. 00:05:43.712 --> 00:05:46.199 The whole question now boils down to 00:05:46.199 --> 00:05:48.382 is the demand for labor, more elastic 00:05:48.382 --> 00:05:51.169 than the supply of labor or vice versa? 00:05:51.169 --> 00:05:53.560 Think about the demanders of labor, businesses, 00:05:53.560 --> 00:05:56.215 what substitutes for labor do they have? 00:05:56.215 --> 00:05:59.859 If the price of labor goes up, what can those businesses do? 00:06:00.159 --> 00:06:02.571 What about the supply of labor, the workers? 00:06:02.665 --> 00:06:05.794 If their wage goes down, what can they do? 00:06:05.794 --> 00:06:07.790 If you think about it, I think you'll see 00:06:07.790 --> 00:06:10.692 that for most workers, especially full time workers, 00:06:10.692 --> 00:06:13.784 they don't really have a lot of good substitutes for work. 00:06:13.784 --> 00:06:16.416 Most workers need some kind of job. 00:06:16.416 --> 00:06:19.906 Even if their wage goes down, they're going to continue to work 00:06:19.906 --> 00:06:22.176 because they need to pay the bills. 00:06:22.176 --> 00:06:24.940 On the other hand, the demanders of labor 00:06:24.940 --> 00:06:26.663 if the wage were to go up, 00:06:26.663 --> 00:06:29.369 they could substitute capital for labor, 00:06:29.369 --> 00:06:31.836 they could move their investments to other countries. 00:06:31.836 --> 00:06:34.096 They have quite a few good substitutes. 00:06:34.096 --> 00:06:35.779 So if that's actually how it works, 00:06:35.779 --> 00:06:38.128 we should probably draw the diagram like this 00:06:38.128 --> 00:06:40.613 with a fairly inelastic supply of labor 00:06:40.613 --> 00:06:43.776 and a fairly elastic demand for labor. 00:06:43.776 --> 00:06:46.849 Economists have done studies of this and on average 00:06:46.849 --> 00:06:48.683 this is what they find. 00:06:48.683 --> 00:06:52.651 So now think about your FICA taxes, that's a tax on labor. 00:06:52.651 --> 00:06:54.127 What's the effect of that? 00:06:54.127 --> 00:06:56.366 Well, it's going to look something like this. 00:06:56.366 --> 00:06:59.165 Notice that the wage paid by buyers of labor, 00:06:59.165 --> 00:07:01.209 that's the wage paid by the firms -- 00:07:01.209 --> 00:07:03.247 that goes up only a little bit. 00:07:03.247 --> 00:07:05.206 On the other hand, the wage received 00:07:05.206 --> 00:07:07.593 by the suppliers of labor, that is the wage 00:07:07.593 --> 00:07:11.498 which the workers end up with, that goes down by a lot. 00:07:11.498 --> 00:07:14.940 And this makes perfect sense when we have a very inelastic 00:07:14.940 --> 00:07:16.436 supply of labor. 00:07:16.436 --> 00:07:19.048 The laborers can't escape the tax and, therefore, 00:07:19.048 --> 00:07:22.338 they end up bearing most of the burden of the tax. 00:07:22.338 --> 00:07:24.595 This doesn't mean, by the way, that we shouldn't have 00:07:24.595 --> 00:07:26.463 social security taxes. 00:07:26.463 --> 00:07:29.181 It may in fact be a good way of forcing people to save 00:07:29.181 --> 00:07:31.329 for their own future, but this does mean 00:07:31.329 --> 00:07:33.829 it is not a free lunch for the workers. 00:07:33.829 --> 00:07:37.082 The workers' wages will drop because of the tax. 00:07:37.082 --> 00:07:39.586 If we didn't have the social security tax, 00:07:39.586 --> 00:07:42.677 wages for most workers would in fact be higher. 00:07:42.677 --> 00:07:46.444 Here's one more application, health insurance mandates. 00:07:46.444 --> 00:07:48.903 Suppose that the government requires employers 00:07:48.903 --> 00:07:51.530 to provide health insurance to their workers 00:07:51.530 --> 00:07:53.899 as is now the case for many employers 00:07:53.899 --> 00:07:55.956 under the Affordable Care Act. 00:07:55.956 --> 00:07:57.380 Who's going to pay for this? 00:07:57.380 --> 00:07:59.121 Who will end up paying for this? 00:07:59.121 --> 00:08:02.915 Is it primarily the employers or primarily the workers? 00:08:02.915 --> 00:08:06.344 It's really just the same analysis as we had before. 00:08:06.344 --> 00:08:09.834 A health insurance mandate is quite similar to a tax. 00:08:09.834 --> 00:08:13.178 A health insurance mandate simply means that the employers 00:08:13.178 --> 00:08:16.512 have to pay a higher wage, but that's just, then, 00:08:16.512 --> 00:08:18.302 the same as a tax. 00:08:18.302 --> 00:08:20.848 What we just saw is that if labor supply 00:08:20.848 --> 00:08:24.901 is less elastic than labor demand, which in many cases makes sense, 00:08:24.901 --> 00:08:27.326 then in that case most of the mandate 00:08:27.326 --> 00:08:29.963 will actually be paid for by the workers. 00:08:29.963 --> 00:08:31.833 Real wages will fall. 00:08:31.833 --> 00:08:35.843 Again this doesn't necessarily mean that the mandate is a bad idea 00:08:35.843 --> 00:08:37.673 but it does mean it's not a free lunch 00:08:37.673 --> 00:08:38.810 for the workers. 00:08:38.810 --> 00:08:41.193 The workers end up paying for their health care 00:08:41.193 --> 00:08:43.685 through the medium of lower wages. 00:08:44.033 --> 00:08:45.991 Taxes have a couple of other effects 00:08:45.991 --> 00:08:48.791 including the raising of revenue and also creating 00:08:48.791 --> 00:08:50.253 some dead weight loss. 00:08:50.253 --> 00:08:53.227 Those are what we're going to look at in the next lecture. 00:08:54.450 --> 00:08:56.124 - [Narrator] If you want to test yourself, 00:08:56.124 --> 00:08:58.528 click Practice questions. 00:08:58.528 --> 00:09:01.654 Or if you're ready to move on, just click Next Video. 00:09:01.654 --> 00:09:05.626 ♪ [music] ♪