WEBVTT 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 ♪ [music] ♪ 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 - [Tyler] In the last lecture, we showed that the legal incidence 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 of a tax does not determine the economic incidence. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 In this lecture, we're going to talk 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 about how the economic incidence of taxes actually is determined. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Who bears the burden of a tax? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Here is the rule for the economic incidence of a tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 The more elastic side of the market will pay 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 a smaller share of the tax, a smaller burden. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Similarly, the less elastic side of the market 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 or rather the more inelastic side of the market will pay 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 a greater share of the tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 So more elastic pays a smaller share, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 less elastic pays a greater share. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 I'm going to show you this in a couple of diagrams 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 and then give you the intuition for why it's the case. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Let's suppose we can't remember the rule. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Is it the more elastic side which bears the smaller share 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 of the tax or the greater share of the tax? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Say we can't quite remember. Well, no problem. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Let's just draw the diagram and read it off as it happens. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 For instance, let's draw a diagram 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 which has a pretty elastic demand curve 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 and relatively speaking a pretty inelastic supply curve. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Here's the price when there's no tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Now let's look at what happens when there is a tax 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 and we'll use our wedge method. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Here's the tax and the height of the wedge gives us 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 the amount of the tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 What do we do? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 We drive this wedge into the diagram 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 until the top of it hits the demand curve 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 and the bottom of it hits the supply curve 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 and then we just read the answer off our diagram. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Point B, this tells us the price paid by the buyer. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Point D, this tells us the price received by the seller. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Let's compare. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 When there was no tax, the price paid by the buyer 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 was at A and with the tax the price to the buyer 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 goes up a little bit to point B. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 The buyer isn't paying much of a higher price. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 On the other hand the seller is receiving a lot less. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 In this case, when demand is more elastic than supply, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 the demanders pay a smaller share of the tax 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 and the suppliers pay a larger share. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Therefore we can just read off the diagram what happens 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 when demand is more elastic than supply. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 You don't have to remember the rule, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 you don't have to memorize it because I'm going to give you 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 some intuition to make it easy in just a moment. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 You simply have to draw the diagram and be able to read 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 the answer off the curves. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Let's look at another case. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 In this case, we've drawn a supply curve which 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 is very inelastic and a demand curve 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 which is less elastic than the supply curve. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Once again we're going to take our tax wedge, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 we're going to push it into the diagram and what happens? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 You can see it right here. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 We just have to read it off the diagram. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Now we see that compared to when there was no tax, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 the price to the buyer has gone up a lot 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 and the price to the sellers has gone down 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 by just a little bit. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 When the supply is more elastic than demand, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 buyers pay the greater share of the tax, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 that is the price to the buyer goes up more 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 than the price to the sellers goes down. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 The buyers pay more of the tax when the supply curve 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 is more elastic. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Let's give some intuition. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 You can always get the right answer by drawing the curves. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 And let's consider the intuition for why that's the case. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 So here's the intuition for remembering the rule. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Think about elasticity as a kind of escape. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 The side of the market which is the more elastic 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 can escape the tax more easily. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Why does that makes sense? Remember what elastic demand means. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 It means that demanders have good substitutes 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 for the taxed good and so they can escape the tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 When the tax is high, the demanders are going to say, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 "We're just going to go buy the substitutes. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 We have plenty of good substitutes." 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 On the other hand, think about what it means 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 when the demand is inelastic. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 It means that there are no good substitutes 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 so it's hard to escape to tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 What about the supply side, elastic supply? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Well, that means the resources which are used to produce 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 the taxed good, they can easily be moved 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 to other industries. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 The resources can move around easily. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 If you try to tax the industry a lot then the land, the capital, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 the workers in that industry which were used 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 to produce the good, they're just going to flow 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 to other industries and so the suppliers 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 can relatively easily escape the tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 On the other hand, if supply is inelastic 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 that means the resources used to produce this good, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 they really can only be used to produce this good. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 They're fixed, they're hard to move around, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 and those factors are not that useful 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 for producing other goods, so that makes it difficult 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 for the suppliers when the supply curve is inelastic. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 That means it's difficult for the suppliers 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 to escape the tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 What if the demanders and the suppliers 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 are both pretty elastic? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Well, here's the thing. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Somebody has to pay the tax, both sides can't escape the tax 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 at least if the good is going to be bought and sold, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 therefore the burden is determined by the relative elasticities. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 It's about which side has it easier to escape the tax 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 and that side will pay less of the tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 The side which is less elastic, they're going to pay 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 more of the tax because that side finds it harder 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 to escape the tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 So let's do an application, say social security taxes. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Last time we showed that the legal incidence 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 of social security taxes has no bearing 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 on the economic incidence, but we didn't say 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 what the economic incidence actually is. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 So let's do that now. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 We're going to have the price of labor up here, the wage, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 and the quantity of labor down here. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 The whole question now boils down to 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 is the demand for labor, more elastic 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 than the supply of labor or vice versa? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Think about the demanders of labor, businesses, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 what substitutes for labor do they have? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 If the price of labor goes up, what can those businesses do? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 What about the supply of labor, the workers? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 If their wage goes down, what can they do? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 If you think about it, I think you'll see 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 that for most workers, especially full time workers, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 they don't really have a lot of good substitutes for work. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Most workers need some kind of job. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Even if their wage goes down. they're going to continue to work 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 because they need to pay the bills. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 On the other hand, the demanders of labor 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 if the wage were to go up, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 they could substitute capital for labor, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 they could move their investments to other countries. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 They have quite a few good substitutes. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 So if that's actually how it works, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 we should probably draw the diagram like this 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 with a fairly inelastic supply of labor 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 and a fairly elastic demand for labor. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Economists have done studies of this and on average 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 this is what they find. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 So now think about your FICA taxes, that's a tax on labor. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 What's the effect of that? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Well, it's going to look something like this. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Notice that the wage paid by buyers of labor, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 that's the wage paid by the firms that goes up 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 only a little bit. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 On the other hand, the wage received 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 by the suppliers of labor, that is the wage 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 which the workers end up with, that goes down by a lot. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 And this makes perfect sense when we have a very inelastic 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 supply of labor. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 The laborers can't escape the tax and, therefore, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 they end up bearing most of the burden of the tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 This doesn't mean, by the way, that we shouldn't have 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 social security taxes. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 It may in fact be a good way of forcing people to save 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 for their own future, but this does mean 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 it is not a free lunch for the workers. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 The workers' wages will drop because of the tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 If we didn't have the social security tax, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 wages for most workers would in fact be higher. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Here's one more application, health insurance mandates. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Suppose that the government requires employers 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 to provide health insurance to their workers 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 as is now the case for many employers 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 under the Affordable Care Act. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Who's going to pay for this? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Who will end up paying for this? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Is it primarily the employers or primarily the workers? 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 It's really just the same analysis as we had before. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 A health insurance mandate is quite similar to a tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 A health insurance mandate simply means that the employers 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 have to pay a higher wage, but that's just, then, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 the same as the tax. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 What we just saw is that if labor supply 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 is less elastic than labor demand, which in many cases makes sense, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 then in that case most of the mandate 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 will actually be paid for by the workers. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Real wages will fall. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Again this doesn't necessarily mean that the mandate is a bad idea 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 but it does mean it's not a free lunch 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 for the workers. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 The workers end up paying for their health care 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 through the medium of lower wages. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Taxes have a couple of other effects 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 including the raising of revenue and also creating 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 some dead weight loss. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Those are what we're going to look at in the next lecture. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 - [Narrator] If you want to test yourself, 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 click Practice questions. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 Or if you're ready to move on, just click Next Video. 99:59:59.999 --> 99:59:59.999 ♪ [music] ♪