1 00:00:00,000 --> 00:00:05,362 ♪ [music] ♪ 2 00:00:09,252 --> 00:00:11,393 - [Tyler] Today we begin the first of several talks 3 00:00:11,393 --> 00:00:13,258 on taxes and subsidies. 4 00:00:13,258 --> 00:00:15,452 We're not going to be talking about income taxes 5 00:00:15,452 --> 00:00:16,957 and income subsidies. 6 00:00:16,957 --> 00:00:19,872 Those are typically topics for macroeconomics. 7 00:00:19,872 --> 00:00:23,486 Instead, we'll be talking about taxes and subsidies on goods, 8 00:00:23,486 --> 00:00:26,339 like a sales tax or a subsidy for wheat. 9 00:00:26,339 --> 00:00:30,057 These are also called commodity taxes and subsidies. 10 00:00:30,057 --> 00:00:31,651 So let's get going. 11 00:00:35,468 --> 00:00:37,932 We're going to be emphasizing three important ideas 12 00:00:37,932 --> 00:00:39,919 about commodity taxation. 13 00:00:39,919 --> 00:00:42,650 First, who pays the tax does not depend 14 00:00:42,650 --> 00:00:45,439 on who writes the check to the government. 15 00:00:45,439 --> 00:00:48,635 For example, suppose the government is taxing apples. 16 00:00:48,680 --> 00:00:50,965 The government could make the buyer of apples 17 00:00:50,965 --> 00:00:53,139 pay for each apple that they buy. 18 00:00:53,139 --> 00:00:56,601 Or they could require the sellers of the apples pay for each apple 19 00:00:56,601 --> 00:00:58,187 that they sell. 20 00:00:58,187 --> 00:01:00,773 What we're going to show is that, from the point of view 21 00:01:00,773 --> 00:01:03,674 of the buyers or sellers, it actually doesn't matter 22 00:01:03,674 --> 00:01:05,424 how the tax is placed. 23 00:01:05,424 --> 00:01:08,380 The actual outcomes are going to be identical. 24 00:01:08,445 --> 00:01:11,626 Another way of putting this is that the economic incidence 25 00:01:11,626 --> 00:01:15,276 of the tax, who actually pays the tax, does not depend 26 00:01:15,276 --> 00:01:18,831 on the legal incidence, who is in law required to write 27 00:01:18,831 --> 00:01:20,385 the check to the government. 28 00:01:20,385 --> 00:01:23,064 This will become a little bit clearer as we go along. 29 00:01:23,064 --> 00:01:25,692 Don't worry about it if it's not clear yet. 30 00:01:25,884 --> 00:01:28,625 The second key point, who pays the tax 31 00:01:28,625 --> 00:01:32,731 does depend on the relative elasticities of demand and supply. 32 00:01:33,113 --> 00:01:36,660 In fact, we can summarize point one and point two by saying, 33 00:01:36,680 --> 00:01:40,635 who pays the tax depends not on the laws of congress 34 00:01:40,635 --> 00:01:43,561 but rather on the laws of supply and demand. 35 00:01:44,332 --> 00:01:46,648 The third point is that commodity taxation 36 00:01:46,648 --> 00:01:49,191 raises revenue, but it also takes away 37 00:01:49,191 --> 00:01:53,144 some gains from trade, that is, it creates deadweight loss. 38 00:01:53,289 --> 00:01:55,648 We're going to be looking at point one in this talk, 39 00:01:55,648 --> 00:01:57,886 and then we'll move on to point two, and point three 40 00:01:57,886 --> 00:01:58,973 in later talks. 41 00:01:58,973 --> 00:02:00,964 So, let's start with point one. 42 00:02:01,130 --> 00:02:04,341 Let's begin our analysis of commodity taxation 43 00:02:04,341 --> 00:02:07,398 by assuming the suppliers are the one who have to send 44 00:02:07,398 --> 00:02:08,796 the check to the government. 45 00:02:08,796 --> 00:02:12,478 That is, the legal incidence of the tax falls on the suppliers. 46 00:02:13,117 --> 00:02:15,614 What does a tax on the suppliers do? 47 00:02:15,614 --> 00:02:17,771 We can think about a tax on suppliers 48 00:02:17,771 --> 00:02:19,820 as increasing their costs. 49 00:02:19,820 --> 00:02:22,412 This is going to shift the supply curve up 50 00:02:22,412 --> 00:02:25,135 by the amount of the tax, so the supply curve 51 00:02:25,135 --> 00:02:26,864 shifts up like this. 52 00:02:27,379 --> 00:02:30,034 Another way of thinking about this, is to remember 53 00:02:30,034 --> 00:02:33,113 that the supply curve tells us the minimum amount 54 00:02:33,113 --> 00:02:36,284 which suppliers require to offer a given quantity 55 00:02:36,284 --> 00:02:38,078 in the marketplace. 56 00:02:38,078 --> 00:02:42,253 The tax, that is going to increase the minimum amount that suppliers 57 00:02:42,253 --> 00:02:45,742 are requiring to offer that quantity in the marketplace. 58 00:02:46,294 --> 00:02:50,181 It shifts up that minimum amount required by just the amount 59 00:02:50,181 --> 00:02:51,445 of the tax. 60 00:02:51,845 --> 00:02:55,015 With the new supply curve we find the new equilibrium. 61 00:02:55,081 --> 00:02:58,311 The market equilibrium moves from point A to point B. 62 00:02:58,664 --> 00:03:02,090 What we see is that of course, the quantity which is exchanged 63 00:03:02,090 --> 00:03:04,635 goes down, in addition, the price paid 64 00:03:04,635 --> 00:03:06,743 by the buyers goes up. 65 00:03:06,747 --> 00:03:08,699 How much do the suppliers get? 66 00:03:08,699 --> 00:03:12,598 The suppliers collect this amount, the price paid by the buyers, 67 00:03:12,598 --> 00:03:14,871 but now they have to give a certain amount of that, 68 00:03:14,871 --> 00:03:16,862 the tax to the government. 69 00:03:16,862 --> 00:03:21,069 The suppliers end up receiving this amount after tax, right here. 70 00:03:21,335 --> 00:03:24,801 In other words, what the tax does, it means that the buyers 71 00:03:24,801 --> 00:03:27,347 pay more than before, and the sellers receive 72 00:03:27,347 --> 00:03:29,221 less than before. 73 00:03:29,221 --> 00:03:32,121 Without any tax, the price the buyers pay 74 00:03:32,121 --> 00:03:35,109 is the same as the price the supplier receives. 75 00:03:35,221 --> 00:03:38,002 With the tax, the buyers pay a certain price, 76 00:03:38,002 --> 00:03:40,047 but the sellers get less than that. 77 00:03:40,047 --> 00:03:43,563 They get whatever the buyers pay minus of course, the tax. 78 00:03:43,935 --> 00:03:46,726 That's the situation when the suppliers pay the tax, 79 00:03:46,726 --> 00:03:49,888 or the suppliers have to send the check to the government. 80 00:03:49,888 --> 00:03:52,542 Let's now look at what happens when it's the buyers 81 00:03:52,542 --> 00:03:54,602 who must send the check to the government. 82 00:03:55,367 --> 00:03:58,061 Now, we look at the situation when the legal incidence 83 00:03:58,061 --> 00:03:59,602 is on the buyers. 84 00:03:59,602 --> 00:04:03,476 We begin just as before with the equilibrium with no taxes. 85 00:04:03,476 --> 00:04:05,717 No taxes on sellers or buyers. 86 00:04:05,717 --> 00:04:08,153 Again, that equilibrium is at point A. 87 00:04:08,153 --> 00:04:10,677 I've also included this supply curve here. 88 00:04:10,677 --> 00:04:13,934 This is the supply curve when the tax is on the suppliers. 89 00:04:13,934 --> 00:04:16,639 It's the supply curve from the previous problem. 90 00:04:16,639 --> 00:04:18,679 It's not relevant for this problem. 91 00:04:18,679 --> 00:04:21,442 I've included it rather to remind us of where 92 00:04:21,442 --> 00:04:24,259 the equilibrium on the previous problem was. 93 00:04:24,259 --> 00:04:27,488 You can think of this as a kind of ghost supply curve. 94 00:04:27,488 --> 00:04:30,260 It's a supply curve from the previous problem 95 00:04:30,260 --> 00:04:32,245 coming back to haunt us. 96 00:04:32,245 --> 00:04:35,211 So what's the effect of a tax on the demanders? 97 00:04:35,211 --> 00:04:37,016 Think about it this way. 98 00:04:37,016 --> 00:04:40,645 Suppose the most you were willing to pay for an apple is $1. 99 00:04:40,645 --> 00:04:44,066 Again, most you're willing to pay for that apple, a dollar, no more. 100 00:04:44,066 --> 00:04:46,743 Now, suppose you learned that the government has instituted 101 00:04:46,743 --> 00:04:48,197 a new tax. 102 00:04:48,197 --> 00:04:51,596 For every apple you buy, you must now pay 25 cents 103 00:04:51,596 --> 00:04:52,763 to the government. 104 00:04:52,763 --> 00:04:54,280 Now, how much are you willing to pay 105 00:04:54,280 --> 00:04:56,821 to suppliers for that apple? 106 00:04:56,821 --> 00:04:59,570 You're only willing to pay the maximum amount 107 00:04:59,570 --> 00:05:01,638 that you're going to be willing to pay suppliers 108 00:05:01,638 --> 00:05:04,126 is now 75 cents. 109 00:05:04,126 --> 00:05:06,752 The maximum amount that apple was worth to you 110 00:05:06,752 --> 00:05:07,902 is a dollar. 111 00:05:07,902 --> 00:05:10,230 If you know you're going to be taxed 25 cents 112 00:05:10,230 --> 00:05:11,432 if you buy that apple, 113 00:05:11,432 --> 00:05:13,810 then the most you're going to be willing to pay the supplier 114 00:05:13,810 --> 00:05:18,617 is 75 cents, because 75 cents plus the 25 cent tax 115 00:05:18,617 --> 00:05:20,904 to the government, that's $1. 116 00:05:20,904 --> 00:05:23,366 That's the most you're willing to pay to get the apple. 117 00:05:23,366 --> 00:05:25,903 In other words, what a tax on demanders does 118 00:05:25,903 --> 00:05:28,160 is it reduces their willingness to pay, 119 00:05:28,160 --> 00:05:30,614 and that means the demand curve shifts. 120 00:05:30,614 --> 00:05:34,344 Which way? The demand curve shifts down by the amount of the tax. 121 00:05:34,978 --> 00:05:36,402 So let's shift. 122 00:05:36,402 --> 00:05:39,690 The tax is exactly the same amount that it was before. 123 00:05:39,690 --> 00:05:43,280 Let's shift the demand curve down by the amount of the tax. 124 00:05:43,724 --> 00:05:45,521 We find now that the new equilibrium 125 00:05:45,521 --> 00:05:47,007 is at point B. 126 00:05:47,007 --> 00:05:50,035 Notice first of all, that the quantity has declined. 127 00:05:50,035 --> 00:05:53,916 The quantity exchange has declined by exactly the same amount 128 00:05:53,916 --> 00:05:56,398 as before in the previous problem. 129 00:05:57,125 --> 00:05:59,732 What about the price received by the sellers? 130 00:05:59,732 --> 00:06:01,976 The sellers now receive this price. 131 00:06:01,976 --> 00:06:05,165 Lo and behold, that's exactly the same price 132 00:06:05,165 --> 00:06:06,587 as it was before. 133 00:06:07,104 --> 00:06:09,506 How about the price paid by the buyers? 134 00:06:09,506 --> 00:06:12,440 The buyers now pay what they paid to the suppliers, 135 00:06:12,440 --> 00:06:15,184 plus they must pay the tax to the government. 136 00:06:15,184 --> 00:06:17,325 This distance is the tax. 137 00:06:17,325 --> 00:06:20,820 Lo and behold, the price after tax paid by the buyers 138 00:06:20,820 --> 00:06:23,633 is once again exactly what it was when the tax 139 00:06:23,633 --> 00:06:25,567 was on the suppliers. 140 00:06:26,169 --> 00:06:29,623 When the tax is on the buyers, the buyers pay more than before. 141 00:06:29,623 --> 00:06:32,005 The sellers receive less than before 142 00:06:32,005 --> 00:06:34,023 by exactly the same amounts. 143 00:06:34,023 --> 00:06:36,878 The quantity declines by the same amount, too. 144 00:06:37,729 --> 00:06:39,996 The net price, or the total price paid 145 00:06:39,996 --> 00:06:42,156 by the buyers is the same. 146 00:06:42,156 --> 00:06:45,451 The total price received by the sellers is the same. 147 00:06:45,760 --> 00:06:48,433 Now that you know the idea, I'm going to show you a simpler way 148 00:06:48,433 --> 00:06:50,128 of demonstrating this. 149 00:06:50,128 --> 00:06:52,519 What we just showed is that it doesn't matter 150 00:06:52,519 --> 00:06:54,398 whether the suppliers must write the check 151 00:06:54,398 --> 00:06:57,148 to the government, or the demanders must write the check 152 00:06:57,148 --> 00:06:59,813 to the government in order to pay the tax. 153 00:06:59,850 --> 00:07:02,114 In other words, we can analyze the tax 154 00:07:02,114 --> 00:07:04,557 by shifting the supply curve up, or by shifting 155 00:07:04,557 --> 00:07:06,389 the demand curve down. 156 00:07:06,681 --> 00:07:09,427 As long as we analyze the same size tax, 157 00:07:09,427 --> 00:07:11,963 we're going to get equivalent outcomes. 158 00:07:11,963 --> 00:07:15,446 It's going to come out the same whichever choice of tax we make. 159 00:07:15,911 --> 00:07:18,284 There's actually a simpler way of thinking about this. 160 00:07:19,032 --> 00:07:21,271 What we can think about such a tax is doing, 161 00:07:21,271 --> 00:07:23,791 is driving a wedge between what the buyer is paying 162 00:07:23,791 --> 00:07:25,621 and what the sellers receive. 163 00:07:25,621 --> 00:07:27,701 When there's no tax, what the buyers pay 164 00:07:27,701 --> 00:07:30,963 is what the sellers receive, but when there's a tax, 165 00:07:30,963 --> 00:07:33,771 the buyers pay more than what the sellers receive. 166 00:07:33,771 --> 00:07:35,830 The difference is what the government gets. 167 00:07:35,830 --> 00:07:38,268 The difference is the amount of the tax. 168 00:07:38,289 --> 00:07:40,756 So let's think about this as a tax wedge. 169 00:07:41,055 --> 00:07:44,979 Let's say this tax wedge, this side is, let's say a dollar. 170 00:07:45,120 --> 00:07:48,013 Another way of analyzing the tax is to drive this wedge 171 00:07:48,013 --> 00:07:50,767 into the diagram until the top of the wedge 172 00:07:50,767 --> 00:07:53,283 hits the demand curve, and the bottom of the wedge 173 00:07:53,283 --> 00:07:55,373 just touches the supply curve. 174 00:07:55,421 --> 00:07:56,774 Let's take a look. 175 00:07:56,795 --> 00:07:58,415 I'm going to drive the wedge in. 176 00:07:58,415 --> 00:08:00,887 What this tells us is that the price the buyer pays 177 00:08:00,887 --> 00:08:03,008 will be here, point B. 178 00:08:03,008 --> 00:08:06,217 The price the suppliers receive will be point D. 179 00:08:06,217 --> 00:08:08,234 The difference is the tax. 180 00:08:08,234 --> 00:08:11,866 For instance, if the buyers end up paying $2.65, 181 00:08:11,866 --> 00:08:16,138 then the sellers must receive $1.65 if the tax is a dollar. 182 00:08:16,584 --> 00:08:21,897 Similarly, if the suppliers receive a $1.65 and the tax is a dollar, 183 00:08:21,897 --> 00:08:24,998 the buyers must be paying $2.65. 184 00:08:24,998 --> 00:08:27,725 With this wedge, we could read off the diagram 185 00:08:27,725 --> 00:08:31,258 the price the buyer pays, the price the seller receives, 186 00:08:31,258 --> 00:08:33,154 and the quantity exchanged. 187 00:08:33,193 --> 00:08:35,212 We don't even have to shift any curves. 188 00:08:35,212 --> 00:08:37,971 We just drive the wedge into this diagram. 189 00:08:38,382 --> 00:08:40,280 Let's do an application. 190 00:08:40,280 --> 00:08:41,708 In the United States, 191 00:08:41,708 --> 00:08:45,039 under the Federal Insurance Contributions Act -- FICA -- 192 00:08:45,039 --> 00:08:49,033 12.4% of earned income up to an annual limit 193 00:08:49,033 --> 00:08:54,580 must be paid into social security, and 2.9%, an additional 2.9% 194 00:08:54,580 --> 00:08:56,953 must be paid into Medicare. 195 00:08:56,953 --> 00:09:00,059 Half of this amount comes directly from the employee. 196 00:09:00,059 --> 00:09:02,354 You can see it on your own paychecks. 197 00:09:02,354 --> 00:09:05,250 This is the FICA tax, and half the amount comes 198 00:09:05,250 --> 00:09:06,820 from the employer. 199 00:09:06,820 --> 00:09:10,393 The question is, does the fact that it's a 50/50 split, 200 00:09:10,393 --> 00:09:12,512 does this make a difference? 201 00:09:12,512 --> 00:09:15,388 Does this mean for example, that since the employer 202 00:09:15,388 --> 00:09:20,012 is paying half that this is necessarily a good deal for the employee? 203 00:09:20,012 --> 00:09:22,059 No, it doesn't mean that. 204 00:09:22,059 --> 00:09:25,736 What we now know is that we could have 100% 205 00:09:25,736 --> 00:09:29,824 of this tax paid by the employee, or we could have 100% 206 00:09:29,824 --> 00:09:32,267 of this tax paid by the employer. 207 00:09:32,267 --> 00:09:35,386 This wouldn't make a difference, not to wages, not to prices, 208 00:09:35,386 --> 00:09:37,068 not to anything. 209 00:09:37,068 --> 00:09:39,852 It would change the legal incidence of the tax, 210 00:09:39,852 --> 00:09:43,265 but it would not change the final economic incidence. 211 00:09:43,841 --> 00:09:46,756 I haven't said here who actually pays the tax. 212 00:09:46,756 --> 00:09:48,484 That's what we're going to be talking about 213 00:09:48,484 --> 00:09:49,769 in the next lecture. 214 00:09:49,769 --> 00:09:52,336 What I've said here is that it doesn't matter 215 00:09:52,336 --> 00:09:55,030 who pays the tax from a legal point-of-view 216 00:09:55,030 --> 00:09:57,380 of who is obliged to deliver that money. 217 00:09:57,380 --> 00:10:00,280 So the legal incidence again, does not have a bearing 218 00:10:00,280 --> 00:10:02,684 on the economic incidence of the tax. 219 00:10:03,377 --> 00:10:05,517 What we're going to talk about in the next lecture 220 00:10:05,517 --> 00:10:09,060 is what does determine the economic incidence of a tax. 221 00:10:09,398 --> 00:10:12,814 It turns out to be elasticities of supply and demand, 222 00:10:12,814 --> 00:10:15,650 and that's what we'll take up in the next lecture. 223 00:10:15,650 --> 00:10:17,454 Thanks again for listening. 224 00:10:18,517 --> 00:10:20,184 - [Narrator] If you want to test yourself, 225 00:10:20,184 --> 00:10:22,389 click "Practice Questions." 226 00:10:22,389 --> 00:10:25,720 Or if you're ready to move on, just click "Next Video." 227 00:10:25,720 --> 00:10:30,798 ♪ [music] ♪