0:00:00.000,0:00:03.320 ♪ [music] ♪ 0:00:08.800,0:00:11.420 - [Prof. Alex Tabarrok] Today we're[br]going to start looking at subsidies. 0:00:11.420,0:00:13.090 We're going to move quite quickly 0:00:13.090,0:00:15.870 because if you've understood[br]the material on taxes, 0:00:15.870,0:00:19.100 the material on subsidies[br]should follow pretty easily. 0:00:19.100,0:00:22.500 However, if you haven't[br]understood the material on taxes, 0:00:22.500,0:00:24.990 this is going to be[br]even more mysterious. 0:00:25.220,0:00:27.390 So make sure you understand taxes 0:00:27.390,0:00:29.270 before we move on to subsidies. 0:00:29.270,0:00:30.140 Here we go. 0:00:34.690,0:00:38.890 Now a subsidy is really[br]just a negative or a reverse tax. 0:00:38.890,0:00:40.430 Instead of taking money, 0:00:40.430,0:00:43.780 the government gives money[br]to consumers or producers. 0:00:44.350,0:00:46.760 Now here are some[br]economic truths about subsidy. 0:00:47.110,0:00:50.110 Who gets the subsidy[br]does not depend 0:00:50.110,0:00:53.010 on who receives the check[br]from the government. 0:00:53.010,0:00:55.990 Once again,[br]the legal incidence of the subsidy -- 0:00:55.990,0:00:57.190 who gets the check -- 0:00:57.190,0:01:00.560 is not the same[br]as the economic incidence. 0:01:00.960,0:01:03.150 That should always[br]already be familiar 0:01:03.150,0:01:05.040 from our discussion of taxes. 0:01:05.720,0:01:08.600 Similarly, who benefits from the subsidy 0:01:08.600,0:01:10.310 does depend 0:01:10.310,0:01:13.820 on the relative elasticities[br]of demand and supply -- 0:01:14.150,0:01:15.970 again, just as with taxes. 0:01:16.390,0:01:20.020 Finally, subsidies must[br]be paid for by taxpayers, 0:01:20.020,0:01:21.320 so instead of revenues, 0:01:21.320,0:01:23.290 there's a cost to a subsidy. 0:01:23.600,0:01:27.280 And they create[br]an inefficient increase in trade, 0:01:27.280,0:01:29.610 also called a deadweight loss. 0:01:29.840,0:01:31.420 Let's take a look in more detail. 0:01:31.420,0:01:33.870 Okay, we have a lot to cover[br]in this diagram 0:01:33.870,0:01:35.070 so put on your thinking hats. 0:01:35.070,0:01:38.010 We begin as usual at the Market --[br]free market equilibrium. 0:01:38.010,0:01:41.780 Let's say that's at price[br]of two dollars and this quantity. 0:01:42.310,0:01:44.590 Now, I'm not going[br]to go through the proof 0:01:44.590,0:01:48.520 that the legal incidence[br]of who gets the subsidy 0:01:48.520,0:01:51.270 does not influence[br]the economic incidence. 0:01:51.640,0:01:55.130 Instead, I'm going[br]to jump right to the key point, 0:01:55.130,0:01:57.480 which is that a subsidy drives a wedge 0:01:57.480,0:02:01.790 between the price received by sellers[br]and the price paid by the buyers. 0:02:01.790,0:02:03.700 The only difference from the tax 0:02:03.700,0:02:07.320 is that the price received[br]by sellers with the subsidy 0:02:07.320,0:02:10.470 is going to be more[br]than the price paid by the buyers. 0:02:11.540,0:02:15.210 So we can use the same[br]wedge analysis that we used before 0:02:15.210,0:02:17.160 except we're going[br]to drive the wedge 0:02:17.160,0:02:19.290 into the diagram[br]from the right hand side. 0:02:19.590,0:02:21.670 So now consider[br]the height of this wedge -- 0:02:21.670,0:02:23.420 let's suppose that's a dollar -- 0:02:23.420,0:02:27.500 and let's drive it in to the diagram[br]until the top hits the supply curve 0:02:27.500,0:02:29.700 and the bottom[br]hits the demand curve. 0:02:29.700,0:02:32.350 This is now going to tell us[br]everything we need to know. 0:02:32.350,0:02:34.500 So at the top, at point B, 0:02:34.500,0:02:37.120 this tells us the price[br]received by sellers -- 0:02:37.120,0:02:38.960 suppose that's $2.40. 0:02:38.960,0:02:41.590 The bottom, at point D, 0:02:41.590,0:02:44.900 tells us the price[br]paid by the buyers -- $1.40. 0:02:44.900,0:02:47.750 Notice that the price[br]received by the sellers 0:02:47.750,0:02:50.240 has got to be $1 more 0:02:50.240,0:02:52.410 than the price paid by the buyers, 0:02:52.410,0:02:55.180 the $1 coming from the subsidy. 0:02:55.790,0:02:58.500 Notice also the key idea -- 0:02:58.500,0:03:01.710 it doesn't matter[br]whether the suppliers 0:03:01.710,0:03:04.320 receive the check[br]from the government, 0:03:04.320,0:03:08.440 or whether the buyers receive[br]the check from the government. 0:03:08.440,0:03:11.150 On net, when all is said and done, 0:03:11.150,0:03:14.550 the sellers will receive[br]$2.40 per unit, 0:03:14.550,0:03:17.680 and the buyers[br]will pay $1.40 per unit. 0:03:18.030,0:03:20.800 By comparing[br]with the free market price, 0:03:20.800,0:03:25.150 we can see who is getting[br]the relative gain from the subsidy. 0:03:25.150,0:03:26.060 In this case, 0:03:26.060,0:03:30.080 both the suppliers and demanders[br]get some of the gain. 0:03:30.080,0:03:33.270 So the suppliers[br]used to get $2 per unit -- 0:03:33.270,0:03:37.140 now they're getting $2.40,[br]so they get 40% of the gain. 0:03:37.520,0:03:40.040 The buyers used to pay $2 -- 0:03:40.040,0:03:44.550 now they're paying $1.40,[br]so they get 60% of the gain. 0:03:44.960,0:03:46.560 Who gets the gain 0:03:46.560,0:03:47.730 is going to depend upon 0:03:47.730,0:03:50.590 the relative elasticities[br]of supply and demand 0:03:50.590,0:03:52.660 and you want[br]to convince yourself of that 0:03:52.660,0:03:54.890 by drawing some more[br]diagrams like this, 0:03:54.890,0:03:57.500 but draw them with[br]a really inelastic supply curve. 0:03:57.500,0:03:58.730 See what happens. 0:03:58.730,0:04:01.720 Then draw it with a more[br]elastic supply curve, 0:04:01.720,0:04:04.680 a supply curve which is more[br]elastic than the demand curve. 0:04:04.680,0:04:07.580 See what happens --[br]so test out different things. 0:04:08.500,0:04:12.960 Next, a tax creates[br]revenues for the government -- 0:04:12.960,0:04:15.840 a subsidy creates[br]costs to the government. 0:04:15.840,0:04:17.330 What is the cost? 0:04:17.330,0:04:22.030 Well, notice that[br]the per unit subsidy is $1 -- 0:04:22.030,0:04:24.550 that's given[br]by the height of the wedge. 0:04:25.210,0:04:27.280 What's the quantity[br]which is subsidized? 0:04:27.280,0:04:29.180 Well, it's this quantity right here. 0:04:29.180,0:04:31.860 So the total cost[br]of the subsidy 0:04:31.860,0:04:34.780 is $1 times the quantity, 0:04:34.780,0:04:38.070 or the subsidy amount[br]times the quantity, 0:04:38.070,0:04:41.560 so it's given by[br]this blue area right here. 0:04:42.710,0:04:44.850 Finally -- got a lot to cover, 0:04:44.850,0:04:47.650 but it should all be[br]fairly standard now -- 0:04:47.650,0:04:51.353 notice that what the subsidy does,[br]another effect of the subsidy, 0:04:51.353,0:04:52.516 not surprisingly, 0:04:52.516,0:04:54.980 is that it increases[br]the quantity exchanged. 0:04:54.980,0:04:57.530 So it increases it from quantity --[br]no subsidy -- 0:04:57.530,0:04:59.920 to the quantity with the subsidy. 0:05:00.330,0:05:03.950 Now, on these additional units exchanged, 0:05:03.950,0:05:07.210 notice what the supply[br]and demand curve tells us. 0:05:07.210,0:05:09.990 It tells us that[br]on those additional units, 0:05:09.990,0:05:14.620 the cost to the suppliers[br]of supplying those units 0:05:14.620,0:05:19.170 exceeds the value[br]to the demanders of those units. 0:05:19.440,0:05:24.340 So, this additional quantity[br]is creating a waste. 0:05:24.690,0:05:28.410 The cost to the suppliers[br]exceeds the value 0:05:28.410,0:05:30.570 of those units to the demanders. 0:05:30.570,0:05:34.060 So the subsidy[br]creates a deadweight loss. 0:05:34.060,0:05:36.700 There's too much trade going on, 0:05:36.700,0:05:38.190 as opposed to the tax -- 0:05:38.190,0:05:41.310 where the tax[br]reduces beneficial trades, 0:05:41.310,0:05:45.540 the subsidy increases[br]wasteful trades. 0:05:45.860,0:05:49.170 Okay, take a good look at[br]this diagram. 0:05:49.170,0:05:52.410 Make sure you understand[br]each part of the diagram, 0:05:52.410,0:05:54.570 and we're going to give[br]some applications 0:05:54.570,0:05:57.220 and give a few more ways[br]of looking at this diagram. 0:05:57.220,0:05:58.780 But this is really the key idea -- 0:05:58.780,0:06:01.020 everything in this diagram[br]right here. 0:06:01.540,0:06:04.890 Do you remember our intuition[br]for who bears the burden of a tax? 0:06:04.890,0:06:08.260 It's that elasticity is like escape. 0:06:08.260,0:06:10.530 So the more elastic[br]the demand curve, 0:06:10.530,0:06:14.300 the more the demanders[br]are able to escape the tax. 0:06:14.300,0:06:17.850 The more elastic the supply curve[br]relative to the demand curve, 0:06:17.850,0:06:21.480 the more able the suppliers[br]are to escape the tax. 0:06:21.480,0:06:23.630 Here I want to give you[br]a similar intuition 0:06:23.630,0:06:27.970 and way of reminding yourself[br]about what happens with the subsidy. 0:06:27.970,0:06:31.060 And that is,[br]when you have no elasticity 0:06:31.060,0:06:34.580 or when you have[br]an inelastic curve, 0:06:34.580,0:06:36.210 then there's no entry. 0:06:36.210,0:06:39.030 No elasticity equals no entry. 0:06:39.030,0:06:40.870 And when there's no entry, 0:06:40.870,0:06:44.350 that's when you gain[br]the benefits of the subsidy. 0:06:44.350,0:06:48.380 When no one can[br]come in to take the subsidy, 0:06:48.380,0:06:49.990 you get the benefit. 0:06:49.990,0:06:52.806 So when there's no elasticity,[br]no entry, 0:06:52.806,0:06:54.993 you get the benefit of the subsidy. 0:06:54.993,0:06:56.450 Let's take a look. 0:06:56.450,0:06:58.410 Let's redo our tax analysis. 0:06:58.410,0:07:01.460 So suppose we have[br]a fairly elastic demand curve 0:07:01.460,0:07:04.150 and a fairly inelastic supply curve, 0:07:04.150,0:07:05.610 and here's our tax wedge. 0:07:05.610,0:07:08.250 We drive it in the diagram[br]and what we see 0:07:08.250,0:07:12.670 is that the suppliers bear[br]more of the burden of the tax. 0:07:12.670,0:07:15.190 That is, the price to them falls. 0:07:15.190,0:07:17.470 They're bearing[br]the brunt of the tax 0:07:17.470,0:07:20.540 because the suppliers[br]have nowhere else to go. 0:07:20.540,0:07:23.960 They can't take their resources[br]used to produce this good 0:07:23.960,0:07:26.880 and use it to produce[br]other goods in the economy. 0:07:26.880,0:07:29.610 The supply is relatively fixed, 0:07:29.610,0:07:33.970 the resources are most useful[br]for producing this particular good, 0:07:33.970,0:07:36.060 so the suppliers cannot escape. 0:07:37.120,0:07:39.000 For the very same reasons, 0:07:39.000,0:07:42.450 the suppliers will get most[br]of the gains of a subsidy. 0:07:42.450,0:07:44.100 So here's our subsidy wedge -- 0:07:44.100,0:07:46.430 we drive it in to the diagram. 0:07:46.430,0:07:50.040 We could read off the diagram here[br]that the price to the suppliers 0:07:50.040,0:07:55.760 is going to rise much more[br]than the price to the buyer falls, 0:07:55.760,0:07:57.520 relative to the market price. 0:07:57.520,0:07:59.150 So what's going on? 0:07:59.150,0:08:03.000 Well, what's going on[br]is that we have this subsidy, 0:08:03.000,0:08:06.050 but because[br]the supply curve is inelastic, 0:08:06.050,0:08:08.090 we don't see a lot of resources 0:08:08.090,0:08:10.810 coming from elsewhere[br]in the economy 0:08:10.810,0:08:15.140 to grab up that subsidy,[br]to take that subsidy. 0:08:15.140,0:08:17.800 The resources[br]in the rest of the economy 0:08:17.800,0:08:20.980 are not good[br]at producing this type of good, 0:08:20.980,0:08:25.100 so it's only the resources[br]which are already in this market, 0:08:25.100,0:08:26.650 the fixed resources -- 0:08:26.650,0:08:29.779 they're the ones which[br]are going to grab up the subsidy. 0:08:29.779,0:08:31.449 The price is going to go up 0:08:31.449,0:08:33.960 because we don't[br]have a lot of resources 0:08:33.960,0:08:37.120 coming from other areas[br]of the economy to produce this good. 0:08:38.390,0:08:40.528 Or we can think about this[br]from the point of view 0:08:40.528,0:08:41.858 of the demanders. 0:08:42.118,0:08:45.070 When the demand[br]is relatively elastic, 0:08:45.070,0:08:46.910 they can escape the tax. 0:08:46.910,0:08:50.540 But, similarly,[br]when the demand is elastic, 0:08:50.540,0:08:53.410 the demanders from other parts[br]of the economy 0:08:53.410,0:08:54.850 with the substitute goods, 0:08:54.850,0:08:57.230 they're going to come in[br]and grab up that subsidy. 0:08:57.230,0:08:59.150 They're going to keep the price high 0:08:59.150,0:09:03.900 because demanders are going to[br]stop consuming the substitute good, 0:09:03.910,0:09:06.250 and they're instead[br]going to move into this market 0:09:06.250,0:09:07.950 to consume this good. 0:09:07.950,0:09:11.620 And because you get[br]all of these demanders 0:09:11.620,0:09:14.610 from elsewhere in the economy[br]coming in to buy this good, 0:09:14.610,0:09:16.990 the price doesn't fall very much. 0:09:17.420,0:09:21.320 Okay, once again,[br]play around with this. 0:09:21.560,0:09:23.540 Draw some demand and supply curves, 0:09:23.540,0:09:26.350 put in a tax wedge,[br]put in a subsidy wedge 0:09:26.350,0:09:28.600 until this all becomes intuitive. 0:09:28.600,0:09:30.900 And remember that,[br]in the case of subsidies, 0:09:30.900,0:09:34.950 no elastic or less elastic[br]means less entry, 0:09:34.950,0:09:39.730 less entry means[br]more gains to the subsidy -- 0:09:39.730,0:09:41.940 they get more[br]of the benefits of the subsidy. 0:09:41.940,0:09:43.550 Let's do an application. 0:09:43.750,0:09:46.250 Farmers in[br]California’s Central Valley 0:09:46.250,0:09:48.220 get a big water subsidy. 0:09:48.220,0:09:51.540 They typically pay $20[br]to $30 an acre-foot for water 0:09:51.540,0:09:55.810 that costs $200 to $500[br]an acre-foot to produce. 0:09:55.810,0:09:58.450 So who benefits[br]the most from this subsidy? 0:09:58.450,0:10:00.860 Is it the California[br]cotton suppliers, 0:10:00.860,0:10:03.710 or is it the buyers[br]of California cotton? 0:10:04.030,0:10:05.930 Let's think about it this way. 0:10:06.130,0:10:08.430 The buyers of California cotton -- 0:10:08.430,0:10:10.300 what kind of substitutes[br]do they have? 0:10:11.030,0:10:12.990 Are they going to have[br]an elastic demand 0:10:12.990,0:10:14.870 or an inelastic demand? 0:10:15.600,0:10:17.550 The buyers of California cotton 0:10:17.550,0:10:20.480 are going to have[br]a very elastic demand, right? 0:10:20.480,0:10:23.550 Because they can substitute[br]cotton grown in Georgia, 0:10:23.550,0:10:26.570 they can substitute[br]cotton grown in Pakistan, 0:10:26.570,0:10:29.500 in India, in many[br]other places in the world. 0:10:29.500,0:10:33.170 In fact, the price of cotton[br]is basically set in a world market, 0:10:33.170,0:10:37.790 so if we have a subsidy[br]for California-cotton suppliers, 0:10:37.790,0:10:40.930 that's not going to push the world[br]price down very much at all. 0:10:40.930,0:10:43.600 It's simply going[br]to induce some buyers 0:10:43.600,0:10:46.140 to buy more California cotton 0:10:46.140,0:10:50.910 and a little bit less of cotton[br]from Pakistan or from India. 0:10:51.200,0:10:54.140 On the other hand,[br]the California cotton suppliers -- 0:10:54.140,0:10:56.650 they've got a pretty[br]inelastic supply curve. 0:10:56.650,0:10:59.170 There's not that much[br]land there to begin with, 0:10:59.170,0:11:02.750 and it's really pretty fixed[br]for growing agricultural goods, 0:11:02.750,0:11:05.870 and probably fairly fixed[br]for growing cotton. 0:11:06.080,0:11:08.830 So, the California cotton suppliers 0:11:08.830,0:11:11.580 are going to get[br]most of the benefits 0:11:11.580,0:11:13.080 of this subsidy. 0:11:13.490,0:11:16.990 It's not going to lower[br]the price of pants at the Gap. 0:11:16.990,0:11:19.820 Instead it's going[br]to go into the pockets 0:11:19.820,0:11:22.910 of the California cotton suppliers,[br]of the farmers. 0:11:23.040,0:11:26.500 Not surprisingly,[br]it's the farmers in California 0:11:26.500,0:11:30.050 who lobby extensively[br]for this subsidy, 0:11:30.050,0:11:32.450 and it's not[br]the consumers of cotton. 0:11:32.450,0:11:33.640 So as we've just shown, 0:11:33.640,0:11:35.740 subsidies can often be wasteful. 0:11:35.740,0:11:38.690 And one of the reasons that[br]we have subsidies is politics -- 0:11:38.690,0:11:41.120 the power of Special[br]Interest Groups in lobbying 0:11:41.120,0:11:41.980 and so forth. 0:11:41.980,0:11:44.210 We'll talk more[br]about that another time. 0:11:44.210,0:11:46.790 However,[br]subsidies can also be useful, 0:11:46.790,0:11:52.020 particularly if there's a reason[br]why the demand for a good 0:11:52.020,0:11:54.860 understates[br]the true value of that good. 0:11:55.680,0:11:58.010 We'll give lots of examples[br]of this type of thing 0:11:58.010,0:12:00.540 when we come[br]to talk about externalities, 0:12:00.540,0:12:04.010 but before we do that I want[br]to give you one more example, 0:12:04.010,0:12:05.990 where this should be[br]fairly intuitive 0:12:05.990,0:12:07.690 and that's wage subsidies. 0:12:08.010,0:12:09.390 So the next lecture, 0:12:09.390,0:12:11.302 we'll look at wage subsidies 0:12:11.302,0:12:14.214 for unskilled[br]or lower-skilled workers 0:12:14.214,0:12:16.304 and we'll compare that[br]with the minimum wage. 0:12:16.304,0:12:17.139 Thanks. 0:12:18.759,0:12:20.409 - [Narrator][br]If you want to test yourself, 0:12:20.409,0:12:22.461 click “Practice Questions.” 0:12:22.741,0:12:26.024 Or, if you're ready to move on,[br]just click “Next Video.” 0:12:26.484,0:12:28.931 ♪ [music] ♪