WEBVTT 00:00:00.031 --> 00:00:05.577 ♪ [music] ♪ 00:00:09.264 --> 00:00:11.711 - [Alex] Today, we begin to discuss elasticity 00:00:11.711 --> 00:00:13.532 and its applications. 00:00:13.532 --> 00:00:15.194 This is going to take us a few lectures 00:00:15.194 --> 00:00:17.445 because the material is a little bit involved 00:00:17.445 --> 00:00:19.701 and also, I'm going to be honest, the material 00:00:19.701 --> 00:00:21.314 can be a little bit tedious. 00:00:21.314 --> 00:00:23.515 There's some formulas that we're going to have to learn 00:00:23.515 --> 00:00:26.181 how to use and memorize and so forth. 00:00:26.181 --> 00:00:29.960 However, the applications are really fascinating. 00:00:29.975 --> 00:00:33.582 Moreover, elasticity is going to come back again and again. 00:00:33.768 --> 00:00:36.399 We're going to use it when we do taxes and subsidies, 00:00:36.399 --> 00:00:39.254 we're going to use it again when we do monopoly. 00:00:39.254 --> 00:00:42.537 This is just another one of those foundational concepts 00:00:42.537 --> 00:00:46.212 that is going to pay to learn well the first time we do it. 00:00:46.212 --> 00:00:47.715 Let's get started. 00:00:51.632 --> 00:00:53.800 Demand curves slope down. 00:00:53.800 --> 00:00:55.717 In other words, when the price goes up, 00:00:55.717 --> 00:00:58.769 the quantity demanded goes down, when the price goes down, 00:00:58.769 --> 00:01:00.936 the quantity demanded goes up. 00:01:00.936 --> 00:01:02.375 Pretty simple. 00:01:02.375 --> 00:01:05.479 But how much does quantity demanded change 00:01:05.479 --> 00:01:07.369 when the price changes? 00:01:07.369 --> 00:01:10.189 When the price goes down, does the quantity demanded 00:01:10.189 --> 00:01:13.265 increase by a lot or by a little? 00:01:13.556 --> 00:01:17.911 That's the concept that elasticity is going to help us to understand. 00:01:18.449 --> 00:01:20.510 Here's the basic terminology. 00:01:20.510 --> 00:01:23.134 A demand curve is said to be elastic 00:01:23.134 --> 00:01:28.005 when an increase in price reduces the quantity demanded by a lot. 00:01:28.491 --> 00:01:33.389 And similarly, when a decrease in price increases the quantity demanded 00:01:33.389 --> 00:01:36.666 by a lot -- that's an elastic curve. 00:01:36.666 --> 00:01:41.181 The quantity is changing a lot in response to the price. 00:01:41.821 --> 00:01:45.333 When the same increase in price reduces the quantity demanded 00:01:45.333 --> 00:01:49.737 just a little or when the same decrease in price increases 00:01:49.737 --> 00:01:52.297 the quantity demanded just a little, 00:01:52.297 --> 00:01:54.905 then the demand curve is said to be inelastic 00:01:54.905 --> 00:01:57.581 or less elastic or not elastic. 00:01:58.015 --> 00:02:01.272 The elasticity of demand is going to be a measure 00:02:01.272 --> 00:02:05.015 of how responsive the quantity demanded is 00:02:05.015 --> 00:02:07.084 to a change in the price. 00:02:07.590 --> 00:02:09.001 Here's an example. 00:02:09.001 --> 00:02:12.046 Let's start with this demand curve which we're going to see 00:02:12.046 --> 00:02:14.720 is an inelastic demand curve. 00:02:15.371 --> 00:02:19.466 Notice that when the price increases from $40 to $50 00:02:19.466 --> 00:02:22.769 that the quantity demanded goes down by just a little, 00:02:22.769 --> 00:02:27.256 by five units from 80 units to 75 units. 00:02:28.223 --> 00:02:30.575 Now consider the following -- suppose we had 00:02:30.575 --> 00:02:32.915 a demand curve like this. 00:02:32.915 --> 00:02:36.022 This turns out to be an elastic demand curve. 00:02:36.022 --> 00:02:40.547 Notice that the same $10 increase in price now reduces 00:02:40.547 --> 00:02:45.473 the quantity demanded from 80 units to 20 units. 00:02:45.473 --> 00:02:49.460 On the elastic demand curve, the quantity demanded 00:02:49.460 --> 00:02:53.694 is much more responsive to the price than it is 00:02:53.694 --> 00:02:56.670 on the inelastic demand curve. 00:02:57.687 --> 00:02:59.995 On a demand curve where the quantity demanded 00:02:59.995 --> 00:03:04.394 is responsive to the price, that's called an elastic demand. 00:03:04.782 --> 00:03:07.006 On a demand curve when the quantity demanded 00:03:07.006 --> 00:03:11.178 isn't responsive or is less responsive to the price, 00:03:11.178 --> 00:03:15.457 that's an inelastic demand or a more inelastic demand, 00:03:15.457 --> 00:03:17.515 a less elastic demand. 00:03:17.766 --> 00:03:20.092 Now you may have noticed on the previous diagrams 00:03:20.092 --> 00:03:23.376 that the inelastic curve had the higher slope. 00:03:23.760 --> 00:03:27.904 That is it was more vertical, while the elastic curve 00:03:27.904 --> 00:03:30.522 was the more horizontal curve. 00:03:30.722 --> 00:03:33.614 We haven't defined elasticity technically yet. 00:03:34.021 --> 00:03:37.055 When we do so, you'll be able to see that elasticity 00:03:37.055 --> 00:03:39.823 is not the same as slope. 00:03:40.170 --> 00:03:41.712 However, they are related. 00:03:42.600 --> 00:03:45.982 For the purposes of this class, if you follow a simple rule, 00:03:45.982 --> 00:03:47.441 you're going to be fine. 00:03:47.441 --> 00:03:51.062 The rule is this -- if two linear demand 00:03:51.062 --> 00:03:54.688 or supply curves run through a common point, 00:03:54.688 --> 00:03:58.612 then at any given quantity, the curve that is flatter, 00:03:58.612 --> 00:04:02.514 more horizontal, that's the more elastic curve. 00:04:02.514 --> 00:04:04.801 So if you're going to draw two demand curves 00:04:04.801 --> 00:04:07.392 which we're going to have to do many times in this class. 00:04:07.392 --> 00:04:09.955 Let's say they run through a common point. 00:04:09.955 --> 00:04:13.087 The flatter one is the more elastic curve, 00:04:13.087 --> 00:04:14.798 that will work fine for you. 00:04:14.798 --> 00:04:16.735 What determines whether a demand curve 00:04:16.735 --> 00:04:19.075 is more or less elastic? 00:04:19.570 --> 00:04:22.001 The key determinant is the availability 00:04:22.001 --> 00:04:23.571 of substitutes. 00:04:23.638 --> 00:04:26.149 As we'll see in a minute, the more substitutes, 00:04:26.149 --> 00:04:28.350 the more elastic the curve. 00:04:28.372 --> 00:04:30.849 We can also give some more specific examples 00:04:30.849 --> 00:04:33.823 that are closely related to the number of substitutes. 00:04:34.342 --> 00:04:37.636 The time horizon -- a longer time horizon 00:04:37.636 --> 00:04:40.201 is going to make the curve more elastic. 00:04:40.763 --> 00:04:43.962 The category of product, a broad category 00:04:43.962 --> 00:04:46.015 is going to be less elastic. 00:04:46.015 --> 00:04:49.000 A specific category, more elastic. 00:04:49.304 --> 00:04:51.200 Necessities versus luxuries. 00:04:51.575 --> 00:04:54.015 Luxuries are going to be more elastic. 00:04:54.234 --> 00:04:56.866 The purchase size -- bigger purchase sizes 00:04:56.866 --> 00:04:59.640 are going to be more elastic. 00:05:00.042 --> 00:05:02.384 Now I've gone through those quickly so don't worry 00:05:02.384 --> 00:05:04.365 if you haven't followed them all right away. 00:05:04.533 --> 00:05:07.278 I'm going to go through them, now, each in turn 00:05:07.278 --> 00:05:08.965 and explain the details. 00:05:08.965 --> 00:05:12.369 The availability of substitutes is really the key determinant 00:05:12.369 --> 00:05:14.932 of how elastic a demand curve is. 00:05:14.932 --> 00:05:16.802 The idea is pretty intuitive. 00:05:16.802 --> 00:05:19.305 If there's lots of substitutes for a good, 00:05:19.305 --> 00:05:21.969 then when the price of that good goes up, 00:05:21.969 --> 00:05:25.598 people are going to switch from it, the good whose price is increased, 00:05:25.598 --> 00:05:27.695 towards the substitutes. 00:05:27.695 --> 00:05:29.616 They're going to buy the substitutes instead. 00:05:30.433 --> 00:05:32.844 That means that when a good with lots of substitutes, 00:05:32.844 --> 00:05:35.029 when the price of that good goes up, 00:05:35.029 --> 00:05:38.431 the quantity demanded is going to go down a lot 00:05:38.431 --> 00:05:41.013 as people switch to the substitutes. 00:05:41.523 --> 00:05:43.237 On the other hand, if we have a good 00:05:43.237 --> 00:05:45.501 which has very few substitutes, 00:05:45.501 --> 00:05:48.650 then consumers are going to find it harder to adjust 00:05:48.650 --> 00:05:50.554 when the price has changed. 00:05:50.554 --> 00:05:54.862 In particular, if the price goes up and there are very few substitutes, 00:05:54.862 --> 00:05:56.837 consumers aren't going to be able to switch 00:05:56.837 --> 00:06:00.391 out of that good into another good. 00:06:00.391 --> 00:06:03.969 So the quantity demanded is going to remain fairly constant. 00:06:04.004 --> 00:06:07.978 It's not going to fall a lot when the good has few substitutes. 00:06:08.473 --> 00:06:10.933 Let's test your understanding with some quick examples. 00:06:11.465 --> 00:06:15.472 Oil, Brazilian coffee, insulin, Bayer Aspirin. 00:06:16.001 --> 00:06:18.651 Which of these goods have an elastic demand? 00:06:18.651 --> 00:06:21.259 Which of them have an inelastic demand? 00:06:21.761 --> 00:06:23.434 Let's start with oil. 00:06:23.434 --> 00:06:26.940 Are there lots of substitutes for oil or just a few substitutes? 00:06:27.639 --> 00:06:29.498 Just a few substitutes, right? 00:06:29.908 --> 00:06:33.331 So if the price of oil goes up tomorrow, 00:06:33.331 --> 00:06:36.614 at that point do we all stop driving our cars? 00:06:36.614 --> 00:06:39.274 No, there aren't very many substitutes, 00:06:39.274 --> 00:06:40.905 at least in the short run. 00:06:40.905 --> 00:06:44.826 Few substitutes that means inelastic demand for oil. 00:06:45.426 --> 00:06:47.474 What about Brazilian coffee? 00:06:47.474 --> 00:06:51.813 Some people love Brazilian coffee but there's also Ethiopian coffee, 00:06:51.813 --> 00:06:54.467 there's Mexican coffee, there's Guatemalan coffee. 00:06:54.467 --> 00:06:58.740 Therefore, lots of substitutes, therefore elastic demand. 00:06:59.121 --> 00:07:02.310 Insulin, if you don't get it you're going to die. 00:07:02.608 --> 00:07:06.492 Not many substitutes, therefore inelastic demand. 00:07:06.983 --> 00:07:08.986 What about Bayer Aspirin? 00:07:08.986 --> 00:07:11.263 If you go to Wal-Mart, you'll find Wal-Mart Aspirin. 00:07:11.263 --> 00:07:13.004 If you go to Target, there's Target Aspirin. 00:07:13.004 --> 00:07:15.295 All kinds of generic aspirins. 00:07:15.295 --> 00:07:18.293 If you understand that aspirin is aspirin, 00:07:18.293 --> 00:07:20.723 you'll understand that there are lots of substitutes. 00:07:21.280 --> 00:07:25.674 If Bayer tries to raise the price of its aspirin too much, 00:07:25.674 --> 00:07:28.986 you'll say, "Forget it. I'm going to go buy the substitutes." 00:07:28.986 --> 00:07:31.798 Therefore, elastic demand. 00:07:31.798 --> 00:07:35.059 The time horizon influences the elasticity of demand 00:07:35.059 --> 00:07:36.351 for a good. 00:07:36.351 --> 00:07:38.659 And really this is just an application of the fact 00:07:38.659 --> 00:07:41.697 that the fundamental determinant is substitutes. 00:07:41.697 --> 00:07:43.970 Immediately following a price increase, 00:07:43.970 --> 00:07:46.806 it's going to be difficult to find substitutes. 00:07:47.418 --> 00:07:51.408 Therefore, immediately following a price increase, demand is likely 00:07:51.408 --> 00:07:55.669 to be fairly inelastic, but over time consumers 00:07:55.669 --> 00:07:59.997 can adjust their behavior and they can find more substitutes. 00:08:00.737 --> 00:08:03.788 For example, if the price of oil goes up, then we know 00:08:03.788 --> 00:08:06.803 that there are very few substitutes in the short run. 00:08:06.803 --> 00:08:09.318 But in the long run, what are some of the things 00:08:09.318 --> 00:08:11.306 that people would do if the price of oil 00:08:11.306 --> 00:08:13.705 stays permanently higher? 00:08:13.705 --> 00:08:17.663 We'll drive smaller cars. They'll switch to mopeds. 00:08:17.663 --> 00:08:20.677 There's a lot more mopeds driven in Europe, for example, 00:08:20.677 --> 00:08:22.630 because for decades, the price of oil 00:08:22.630 --> 00:08:26.083 has been higher in Europe due to taxes. 00:08:26.083 --> 00:08:28.662 People have adjusted. 00:08:28.662 --> 00:08:31.201 In the long run, people will even adjust 00:08:31.201 --> 00:08:34.168 how cities are designed so that more people 00:08:34.168 --> 00:08:37.001 will live in apartments closer to where they work 00:08:37.001 --> 00:08:39.117 if the price of oil stays high. 00:08:39.620 --> 00:08:43.230 If the price of oil is really low, there'll be more sprawl. 00:08:43.519 --> 00:08:45.908 People will be more willing to live far away 00:08:45.908 --> 00:08:49.121 and have a big lawn if the price of oil isn't so high. 00:08:50.029 --> 00:08:54.234 The longer the time horizon, the more the ability to adjust, 00:08:54.282 --> 00:08:58.564 the more substitutes, and thus, the more elastic the demand. 00:08:58.966 --> 00:09:02.715 Another factor determining the elasticity of demand, again, 00:09:02.715 --> 00:09:04.575 based upon the fundamental question: 00:09:04.575 --> 00:09:07.330 are there lots of substitutes or just a few 00:09:07.330 --> 00:09:10.504 is what we might call the classification of the good. 00:09:10.516 --> 00:09:14.034 The broader the classification, the less likely consumers 00:09:14.034 --> 00:09:16.435 will be able to find a substitute. 00:09:16.435 --> 00:09:19.855 The narrower the classification, the more likely consumers 00:09:19.855 --> 00:09:22.136 will be able to find a substitute. 00:09:22.136 --> 00:09:24.302 We've already seen an example of this. 00:09:24.302 --> 00:09:26.934 There are more substitutes for Bayer Aspirin, 00:09:26.934 --> 00:09:30.553 a narrow classification, than there are for aspirin, 00:09:30.553 --> 00:09:32.898 a wider classification. 00:09:32.898 --> 00:09:35.464 If the price of Bayer Aspirin goes up, 00:09:35.464 --> 00:09:37.919 there are more substitutes -- the generics. 00:09:37.919 --> 00:09:40.760 If the price of all aspirin goes up, 00:09:40.760 --> 00:09:42.968 there are fewer substitutes. 00:09:42.968 --> 00:09:45.511 Of course, there are still some, like ibuprofen 00:09:45.511 --> 00:09:47.827 and acetaminophen and so forth. 00:09:47.827 --> 00:09:50.386 But the narrower the classification, 00:09:50.386 --> 00:09:54.040 the more substitutes, the more elastic the demand. 00:09:54.058 --> 00:09:56.737 Another example, the demand for food. 00:09:56.737 --> 00:10:00.157 A broad classification is less elastic 00:10:00.157 --> 00:10:03.744 than the demand for lettuce, a particular type of food, 00:10:03.744 --> 00:10:06.003 a narrow classification. 00:10:06.003 --> 00:10:09.689 Therefore the demand for lettuce would be more elastic 00:10:09.689 --> 00:10:11.698 than the demand for food. 00:10:11.698 --> 00:10:14.218 The nature of the good in the consumer's mind 00:10:14.218 --> 00:10:16.242 can also affect the elasticity. 00:10:16.242 --> 00:10:19.542 In particular, whether the good is thought of as a necessity 00:10:19.542 --> 00:10:21.483 or as a luxury. 00:10:21.483 --> 00:10:24.331 Now don't take these categories as somehow being out there 00:10:24.331 --> 00:10:25.611 in the world. 00:10:25.611 --> 00:10:27.616 They are more about a person's tastes. 00:10:27.616 --> 00:10:30.289 For example, for some consumers that coffee in the morning 00:10:30.289 --> 00:10:32.014 is a necessity. 00:10:32.014 --> 00:10:34.927 Even if the price of coffee goes up by a lot, 00:10:34.927 --> 00:10:38.003 those consumers will still continue to consume 00:10:38.003 --> 00:10:40.341 about the same amount of coffee. 00:10:40.341 --> 00:10:43.689 Therefore, those consumers will have an inelastic demand. 00:10:43.689 --> 00:10:47.143 They'll have an inelastic demand for goods that they consider 00:10:47.143 --> 00:10:49.058 to be necessities. 00:10:49.461 --> 00:10:51.259 The same good in someone else's mind 00:10:51.259 --> 00:10:52.540 might be a luxury. 00:10:52.540 --> 00:10:55.287 The consumer who occasionally has a cup of coffee. 00:10:55.287 --> 00:10:56.525 If the price goes up, 00:10:56.525 --> 00:10:58.342 then they're going to be more willing to say, 00:10:58.342 --> 00:11:00.737 "Nah, I'm going to switch to tea. I'm going to switch 00:11:00.737 --> 00:11:02.289 to something else." 00:11:02.289 --> 00:11:05.926 Depending upon how consumers regard the good therefore 00:11:05.926 --> 00:11:09.300 as a necessity, more inelastic demand. 00:11:09.300 --> 00:11:12.733 As a luxury, more elastic demand. 00:11:12.733 --> 00:11:15.659 The final determinant is the size of the purchase 00:11:15.659 --> 00:11:18.112 relative to a consumer's budget. 00:11:18.112 --> 00:11:20.855 If the purchase is small relative to the budget, 00:11:20.855 --> 00:11:24.017 then consumers may not even notice when the price goes up. 00:11:24.017 --> 00:11:26.581 And if they don't notice, they're not going to respond 00:11:26.581 --> 00:11:29.363 with a big change in the quantity demanded. 00:11:29.363 --> 00:11:31.256 On the other hand, if we have a product 00:11:31.256 --> 00:11:33.461 which is a large part of the budget, 00:11:33.461 --> 00:11:35.239 consumers will notice. 00:11:35.239 --> 00:11:38.440 Consumers notice when the price of automobiles goes up -- 00:11:38.440 --> 00:11:40.299 that's a big purchase. 00:11:40.299 --> 00:11:42.418 They're going to shop around a lot. 00:11:42.418 --> 00:11:44.707 They're going to try and get a big bargain 00:11:44.707 --> 00:11:46.680 when the purchase is a large fraction 00:11:46.680 --> 00:11:48.453 of their budget. 00:11:48.453 --> 00:11:51.021 On the other hand, when the price of toothpicks 00:11:51.021 --> 00:11:53.980 goes up by a lot, that's not such a big deal. 00:11:53.980 --> 00:11:56.368 Consumers probably won't even notice 00:11:56.368 --> 00:11:58.978 whether toothpicks are $0.50 or a $1. 00:11:58.978 --> 00:12:01.703 That's a 50% increase in price, 00:12:01.703 --> 00:12:04.852 but you probably don't even notice that at the store. 00:12:05.223 --> 00:12:10.158 So small item at least in the short run more inelastic. 00:12:10.542 --> 00:12:12.798 Bigger items, the bigger part of the budget, 00:12:12.798 --> 00:12:18.410 ones the consumer notices, more elastic, more price sensitive. 00:12:18.991 --> 00:12:22.762 Let's summarize the determinants of the elasticity of demand. 00:12:22.968 --> 00:12:26.017 For less elastic goods, that means fewer substitutes. 00:12:26.250 --> 00:12:29.648 Short run, less time to adjust, necessities, 00:12:29.648 --> 00:12:31.493 small part of the budget. 00:12:31.771 --> 00:12:35.144 Each of these factors makes the demand curve less elastic. 00:12:36.685 --> 00:12:39.982 More elastic demand, that means more substitutes. 00:12:39.982 --> 00:12:45.321 Long run, more time to adjust. Luxuries, large part of the budget. 00:12:45.321 --> 00:12:48.564 These factors make a demand curve more elastic. 00:12:48.924 --> 00:12:52.743 If you have to, memorize these, but once you understand 00:12:52.743 --> 00:12:55.272 that elasticity means how responsive 00:12:55.272 --> 00:12:58.740 is the quantity demanded to a change in the price, 00:12:58.740 --> 00:13:03.350 then you'll be able to recreate or figure out these factors again. 00:13:04.485 --> 00:13:06.710 That's it for the elasticity of demand. 00:13:06.710 --> 00:13:09.953 Next time,we're going to take a closer look at technically 00:13:09.953 --> 00:13:11.599 how do we get a number? 00:13:11.599 --> 00:13:14.155 How do we calculate the elasticity of demand? 00:13:14.155 --> 00:13:17.707 Given some facts and figures on prices and quantity demanded, 00:13:17.707 --> 00:13:20.699 how do we calculate what the elasticity really is? 00:13:20.699 --> 00:13:22.470 What's the number? 00:13:23.630 --> 00:13:25.322 - [Narrator] If you want to test yourself, 00:13:25.322 --> 00:13:27.606 click Practice questions. 00:13:27.606 --> 00:13:30.971 Or if you're ready to move on, just click Next Video. 00:13:30.971 --> 00:13:35.981 ♪ [music] ♪