1 00:00:00,031 --> 00:00:05,577 ♪ [music] ♪ 2 00:00:09,264 --> 00:00:11,711 - [Alex] Today, we begin to discuss elasticity 3 00:00:11,711 --> 00:00:13,532 and its applications. 4 00:00:13,532 --> 00:00:15,194 This is going to take us a few lectures 5 00:00:15,194 --> 00:00:17,445 because the material is a little bit involved 6 00:00:17,445 --> 00:00:19,701 and also, I'm going to be honest, the material 7 00:00:19,701 --> 00:00:21,314 can be a little bit tedious. 8 00:00:21,314 --> 00:00:23,515 There's some formulas that we're going to have to learn 9 00:00:23,515 --> 00:00:26,181 how to use and memorize and so forth. 10 00:00:26,181 --> 00:00:29,960 However, the applications are really fascinating. 11 00:00:29,975 --> 00:00:33,582 Moreover, elasticity is going to come back again and again. 12 00:00:33,768 --> 00:00:36,399 We're going to use it when we do taxes and subsidies, 13 00:00:36,399 --> 00:00:39,254 we're going to use it again when we do monopoly. 14 00:00:39,254 --> 00:00:42,537 This is just another one of those foundational concepts 15 00:00:42,537 --> 00:00:46,212 that is going to pay to learn well the first time we do it. 16 00:00:46,212 --> 00:00:47,715 Let's get started. 17 00:00:51,632 --> 00:00:53,800 Demand curves slope down. 18 00:00:53,800 --> 00:00:55,717 In other words, when the price goes up, 19 00:00:55,717 --> 00:00:58,769 the quantity demanded goes down, when the price goes down, 20 00:00:58,769 --> 00:01:00,936 the quantity demanded goes up. 21 00:01:00,936 --> 00:01:02,375 Pretty simple. 22 00:01:02,375 --> 00:01:05,479 But how much does quantity demanded change 23 00:01:05,479 --> 00:01:07,369 when the price changes? 24 00:01:07,369 --> 00:01:10,189 When the price goes down, does the quantity demanded 25 00:01:10,189 --> 00:01:13,265 increase by a lot or by a little? 26 00:01:13,556 --> 00:01:17,911 That's the concept that elasticity is going to help us to understand. 27 00:01:18,449 --> 00:01:20,510 Here's the basic terminology. 28 00:01:20,510 --> 00:01:23,134 A demand curve is said to be elastic 29 00:01:23,134 --> 00:01:28,005 when an increase in price reduces the quantity demanded by a lot. 30 00:01:28,491 --> 00:01:33,389 And similarly, when a decrease in price increases the quantity demanded 31 00:01:33,389 --> 00:01:36,666 by a lot -- that's an elastic curve. 32 00:01:36,666 --> 00:01:41,181 The quantity is changing a lot in response to the price. 33 00:01:41,821 --> 00:01:45,333 When the same increase in price reduces the quantity demanded 34 00:01:45,333 --> 00:01:49,737 just a little or when the same decrease in price increases 35 00:01:49,737 --> 00:01:52,297 the quantity demanded just a little, 36 00:01:52,297 --> 00:01:54,905 then the demand curve is said to be inelastic 37 00:01:54,905 --> 00:01:57,581 or less elastic or not elastic. 38 00:01:58,015 --> 00:02:01,272 The elasticity of demand is going to be a measure 39 00:02:01,272 --> 00:02:05,015 of how responsive the quantity demanded is 40 00:02:05,015 --> 00:02:07,084 to a change in the price. 41 00:02:07,590 --> 00:02:09,001 Here's an example. 42 00:02:09,001 --> 00:02:12,046 Let's start with this demand curve which we're going to see 43 00:02:12,046 --> 00:02:14,720 is an inelastic demand curve. 44 00:02:15,371 --> 00:02:19,466 Notice that when the price increases from $40 to $50 45 00:02:19,466 --> 00:02:22,769 that the quantity demanded goes down by just a little, 46 00:02:22,769 --> 00:02:27,256 by five units from 80 units to 75 units. 47 00:02:28,223 --> 00:02:30,575 Now consider the following -- suppose we had 48 00:02:30,575 --> 00:02:32,915 a demand curve like this. 49 00:02:32,915 --> 00:02:36,022 This turns out to be an elastic demand curve. 50 00:02:36,022 --> 00:02:40,547 Notice that the same $10 increase in price now reduces 51 00:02:40,547 --> 00:02:45,473 the quantity demanded from 80 units to 20 units. 52 00:02:45,473 --> 00:02:49,460 On the elastic demand curve, the quantity demanded 53 00:02:49,460 --> 00:02:53,694 is much more responsive to the price than it is 54 00:02:53,694 --> 00:02:56,670 on the inelastic demand curve. 55 00:02:57,687 --> 00:02:59,995 On a demand curve where the quantity demanded 56 00:02:59,995 --> 00:03:04,394 is responsive to the price, that's called an elastic demand. 57 00:03:04,782 --> 00:03:07,006 On a demand curve when the quantity demanded 58 00:03:07,006 --> 00:03:11,178 isn't responsive or is less responsive to the price, 59 00:03:11,178 --> 00:03:15,457 that's an inelastic demand or a more inelastic demand, 60 00:03:15,457 --> 00:03:17,515 a less elastic demand. 61 00:03:17,766 --> 00:03:20,092 Now you may have noticed on the previous diagrams 62 00:03:20,092 --> 00:03:23,376 that the inelastic curve had the higher slope. 63 00:03:23,760 --> 00:03:27,904 That is it was more vertical, while the elastic curve 64 00:03:27,904 --> 00:03:30,522 was the more horizontal curve. 65 00:03:30,722 --> 00:03:33,614 We haven't defined elasticity technically yet. 66 00:03:34,021 --> 00:03:37,055 When we do so, you'll be able to see that elasticity 67 00:03:37,055 --> 00:03:39,823 is not the same as slope. 68 00:03:40,170 --> 00:03:41,712 However, they are related. 69 00:03:42,600 --> 00:03:45,982 For the purposes of this class, if you follow a simple rule, 70 00:03:45,982 --> 00:03:47,441 you're going to be fine. 71 00:03:47,441 --> 00:03:51,062 The rule is this -- if two linear demand 72 00:03:51,062 --> 00:03:54,688 or supply curves run through a common point, 73 00:03:54,688 --> 00:03:58,612 then at any given quantity, the curve that is flatter, 74 00:03:58,612 --> 00:04:02,514 more horizontal, that's the more elastic curve. 75 00:04:02,514 --> 00:04:04,801 So if you're going to draw two demand curves 76 00:04:04,801 --> 00:04:07,392 which we're going to have to do many times in this class. 77 00:04:07,392 --> 00:04:09,955 Let's say they run through a common point. 78 00:04:09,955 --> 00:04:13,087 The flatter one is the more elastic curve, 79 00:04:13,087 --> 00:04:14,798 that will work fine for you. 80 00:04:14,798 --> 00:04:16,735 What determines whether a demand curve 81 00:04:16,735 --> 00:04:19,075 is more or less elastic? 82 00:04:19,570 --> 00:04:22,001 The key determinant is the availability 83 00:04:22,001 --> 00:04:23,571 of substitutes. 84 00:04:23,638 --> 00:04:26,149 As we'll see in a minute, the more substitutes, 85 00:04:26,149 --> 00:04:28,350 the more elastic the curve. 86 00:04:28,372 --> 00:04:30,849 We can also give some more specific examples 87 00:04:30,849 --> 00:04:33,823 that are closely related to the number of substitutes. 88 00:04:34,342 --> 00:04:37,636 The time horizon -- a longer time horizon 89 00:04:37,636 --> 00:04:40,201 is going to make the curve more elastic. 90 00:04:40,763 --> 00:04:43,962 The category of product, a broad category 91 00:04:43,962 --> 00:04:46,015 is going to be less elastic. 92 00:04:46,015 --> 00:04:49,000 A specific category, more elastic. 93 00:04:49,304 --> 00:04:51,200 Necessities versus luxuries. 94 00:04:51,575 --> 00:04:54,015 Luxuries are going to be more elastic. 95 00:04:54,234 --> 00:04:56,866 The purchase size -- bigger purchase sizes 96 00:04:56,866 --> 00:04:59,640 are going to be more elastic. 97 00:05:00,042 --> 00:05:02,384 Now I've gone through those quickly so don't worry 98 00:05:02,384 --> 00:05:04,365 if you haven't followed them all right away. 99 00:05:04,533 --> 00:05:07,278 I'm going to go through them, now, each in turn 100 00:05:07,278 --> 00:05:08,965 and explain the details. 101 00:05:08,965 --> 00:05:12,369 The availability of substitutes is really the key determinant 102 00:05:12,369 --> 00:05:14,932 of how elastic a demand curve is. 103 00:05:14,932 --> 00:05:16,802 The idea is pretty intuitive. 104 00:05:16,802 --> 00:05:19,305 If there's lots of substitutes for a good, 105 00:05:19,305 --> 00:05:21,969 then when the price of that good goes up, 106 00:05:21,969 --> 00:05:25,598 people are going to switch from it, the good whose price is increased, 107 00:05:25,598 --> 00:05:27,695 towards the substitutes. 108 00:05:27,695 --> 00:05:29,616 They're going to buy the substitutes instead. 109 00:05:30,433 --> 00:05:32,844 That means that when a good with lots of substitutes, 110 00:05:32,844 --> 00:05:35,029 when the price of that good goes up, 111 00:05:35,029 --> 00:05:38,431 the quantity demanded is going to go down a lot 112 00:05:38,431 --> 00:05:41,013 as people switch to the substitutes. 113 00:05:41,523 --> 00:05:43,237 On the other hand, if we have a good 114 00:05:43,237 --> 00:05:45,501 which has very few substitutes, 115 00:05:45,501 --> 00:05:48,650 then consumers are going to find it harder to adjust 116 00:05:48,650 --> 00:05:50,554 when the price has changed. 117 00:05:50,554 --> 00:05:54,862 In particular, if the price goes up and there are very few substitutes, 118 00:05:54,862 --> 00:05:56,837 consumers aren't going to be able to switch 119 00:05:56,837 --> 00:06:00,391 out of that good into another good. 120 00:06:00,391 --> 00:06:03,969 So the quantity demanded is going to remain fairly constant. 121 00:06:04,004 --> 00:06:07,978 It's not going to fall a lot when the good has few substitutes. 122 00:06:08,473 --> 00:06:10,933 Let's test your understanding with some quick examples. 123 00:06:11,465 --> 00:06:15,472 Oil, Brazilian coffee, insulin, Bayer Aspirin. 124 00:06:16,001 --> 00:06:18,651 Which of these goods have an elastic demand? 125 00:06:18,651 --> 00:06:21,259 Which of them have an inelastic demand? 126 00:06:21,761 --> 00:06:23,434 Let's start with oil. 127 00:06:23,434 --> 00:06:26,940 Are there lots of substitutes for oil or just a few substitutes? 128 00:06:27,639 --> 00:06:29,498 Just a few substitutes, right? 129 00:06:29,908 --> 00:06:33,331 So if the price of oil goes up tomorrow, 130 00:06:33,331 --> 00:06:36,614 at that point do we all stop driving our cars? 131 00:06:36,614 --> 00:06:39,274 No, there aren't very many substitutes, 132 00:06:39,274 --> 00:06:40,905 at least in the short run. 133 00:06:40,905 --> 00:06:44,826 Few substitutes that means inelastic demand for oil. 134 00:06:45,426 --> 00:06:47,474 What about Brazilian coffee? 135 00:06:47,474 --> 00:06:51,813 Some people love Brazilian coffee but there's also Ethiopian coffee, 136 00:06:51,813 --> 00:06:54,467 there's Mexican coffee, there's Guatemalan coffee. 137 00:06:54,467 --> 00:06:58,740 Therefore, lots of substitutes, therefore elastic demand. 138 00:06:59,121 --> 00:07:02,310 Insulin, if you don't get it you're going to die. 139 00:07:02,608 --> 00:07:06,492 Not many substitutes, therefore inelastic demand. 140 00:07:06,983 --> 00:07:08,986 What about Bayer Aspirin? 141 00:07:08,986 --> 00:07:11,263 If you go to Wal-Mart, you'll find Wal-Mart Aspirin. 142 00:07:11,263 --> 00:07:13,004 If you go to Target, there's Target Aspirin. 143 00:07:13,004 --> 00:07:15,295 All kinds of generic aspirins. 144 00:07:15,295 --> 00:07:18,293 If you understand that aspirin is aspirin, 145 00:07:18,293 --> 00:07:20,723 you'll understand that there are lots of substitutes. 146 00:07:21,280 --> 00:07:25,674 If Bayer tries to raise the price of its aspirin too much, 147 00:07:25,674 --> 00:07:28,986 you'll say, "Forget it. I'm going to go buy the substitutes." 148 00:07:28,986 --> 00:07:31,798 Therefore, elastic demand. 149 00:07:31,798 --> 00:07:35,059 The time horizon influences the elasticity of demand 150 00:07:35,059 --> 00:07:36,351 for a good. 151 00:07:36,351 --> 00:07:38,659 And really this is just an application of the fact 152 00:07:38,659 --> 00:07:41,697 that the fundamental determinant is substitutes. 153 00:07:41,697 --> 00:07:43,970 Immediately following a price increase, 154 00:07:43,970 --> 00:07:46,806 it's going to be difficult to find substitutes. 155 00:07:47,418 --> 00:07:51,408 Therefore, immediately following a price increase, demand is likely 156 00:07:51,408 --> 00:07:55,669 to be fairly inelastic, but over time consumers 157 00:07:55,669 --> 00:07:59,997 can adjust their behavior and they can find more substitutes. 158 00:08:00,737 --> 00:08:03,788 For example, if the price of oil goes up, then we know 159 00:08:03,788 --> 00:08:06,803 that there are very few substitutes in the short run. 160 00:08:06,803 --> 00:08:09,318 But in the long run, what are some of the things 161 00:08:09,318 --> 00:08:11,306 that people would do if the price of oil 162 00:08:11,306 --> 00:08:13,705 stays permanently higher? 163 00:08:13,705 --> 00:08:17,663 We'll drive smaller cars. They'll switch to mopeds. 164 00:08:17,663 --> 00:08:20,677 There's a lot more mopeds driven in Europe, for example, 165 00:08:20,677 --> 00:08:22,630 because for decades, the price of oil 166 00:08:22,630 --> 00:08:26,083 has been higher in Europe due to taxes. 167 00:08:26,083 --> 00:08:28,662 People have adjusted. 168 00:08:28,662 --> 00:08:31,201 In the long run, people will even adjust 169 00:08:31,201 --> 00:08:34,168 how cities are designed so that more people 170 00:08:34,168 --> 00:08:37,001 will live in apartments closer to where they work 171 00:08:37,001 --> 00:08:39,117 if the price of oil stays high. 172 00:08:39,620 --> 00:08:43,230 If the price of oil is really low, there'll be more sprawl. 173 00:08:43,519 --> 00:08:45,908 People will be more willing to live far away 174 00:08:45,908 --> 00:08:49,121 and have a big lawn if the price of oil isn't so high. 175 00:08:50,029 --> 00:08:54,234 The longer the time horizon, the more the ability to adjust, 176 00:08:54,282 --> 00:08:58,564 the more substitutes, and thus, the more elastic the demand. 177 00:08:58,966 --> 00:09:02,715 Another factor determining the elasticity of demand, again, 178 00:09:02,715 --> 00:09:04,575 based upon the fundamental question: 179 00:09:04,575 --> 00:09:07,330 are there lots of substitutes or just a few 180 00:09:07,330 --> 00:09:10,504 is what we might call the classification of the good. 181 00:09:10,516 --> 00:09:14,034 The broader the classification, the less likely consumers 182 00:09:14,034 --> 00:09:16,435 will be able to find a substitute. 183 00:09:16,435 --> 00:09:19,855 The narrower the classification, the more likely consumers 184 00:09:19,855 --> 00:09:22,136 will be able to find a substitute. 185 00:09:22,136 --> 00:09:24,302 We've already seen an example of this. 186 00:09:24,302 --> 00:09:26,934 There are more substitutes for Bayer Aspirin, 187 00:09:26,934 --> 00:09:30,553 a narrow classification, than there are for aspirin, 188 00:09:30,553 --> 00:09:32,898 a wider classification. 189 00:09:32,898 --> 00:09:35,464 If the price of Bayer Aspirin goes up, 190 00:09:35,464 --> 00:09:37,919 there are more substitutes -- the generics. 191 00:09:37,919 --> 00:09:40,760 If the price of all aspirin goes up, 192 00:09:40,760 --> 00:09:42,968 there are fewer substitutes. 193 00:09:42,968 --> 00:09:45,511 Of course, there are still some, like ibuprofen 194 00:09:45,511 --> 00:09:47,827 and acetaminophen and so forth. 195 00:09:47,827 --> 00:09:50,386 But the narrower the classification, 196 00:09:50,386 --> 00:09:54,040 the more substitutes, the more elastic the demand. 197 00:09:54,058 --> 00:09:56,737 Another example, the demand for food. 198 00:09:56,737 --> 00:10:00,157 A broad classification is less elastic 199 00:10:00,157 --> 00:10:03,744 than the demand for lettuce, a particular type of food, 200 00:10:03,744 --> 00:10:06,003 a narrow classification. 201 00:10:06,003 --> 00:10:09,689 Therefore the demand for lettuce would be more elastic 202 00:10:09,689 --> 00:10:11,698 than the demand for food. 203 00:10:11,698 --> 00:10:14,218 The nature of the good in the consumer's mind 204 00:10:14,218 --> 00:10:16,242 can also affect the elasticity. 205 00:10:16,242 --> 00:10:19,542 In particular, whether the good is thought of as a necessity 206 00:10:19,542 --> 00:10:21,483 or as a luxury. 207 00:10:21,483 --> 00:10:24,331 Now don't take these categories as somehow being out there 208 00:10:24,331 --> 00:10:25,611 in the world. 209 00:10:25,611 --> 00:10:27,616 They are more about a person's tastes. 210 00:10:27,616 --> 00:10:30,289 For example, for some consumers that coffee in the morning 211 00:10:30,289 --> 00:10:32,014 is a necessity. 212 00:10:32,014 --> 00:10:34,927 Even if the price of coffee goes up by a lot, 213 00:10:34,927 --> 00:10:38,003 those consumers will still continue to consume 214 00:10:38,003 --> 00:10:40,341 about the same amount of coffee. 215 00:10:40,341 --> 00:10:43,689 Therefore, those consumers will have an inelastic demand. 216 00:10:43,689 --> 00:10:47,143 They'll have an inelastic demand for goods that they consider 217 00:10:47,143 --> 00:10:49,058 to be necessities. 218 00:10:49,461 --> 00:10:51,259 The same good in someone else's mind 219 00:10:51,259 --> 00:10:52,540 might be a luxury. 220 00:10:52,540 --> 00:10:55,287 The consumer who occasionally has a cup of coffee. 221 00:10:55,287 --> 00:10:56,525 If the price goes up, 222 00:10:56,525 --> 00:10:58,342 then they're going to be more willing to say, 223 00:10:58,342 --> 00:11:00,737 "Nah, I'm going to switch to tea. I'm going to switch 224 00:11:00,737 --> 00:11:02,289 to something else." 225 00:11:02,289 --> 00:11:05,926 Depending upon how consumers regard the good therefore 226 00:11:05,926 --> 00:11:09,300 as a necessity, more inelastic demand. 227 00:11:09,300 --> 00:11:12,733 As a luxury, more elastic demand. 228 00:11:12,733 --> 00:11:15,659 The final determinant is the size of the purchase 229 00:11:15,659 --> 00:11:18,112 relative to a consumer's budget. 230 00:11:18,112 --> 00:11:20,855 If the purchase is small relative to the budget, 231 00:11:20,855 --> 00:11:24,017 then consumers may not even notice when the price goes up. 232 00:11:24,017 --> 00:11:26,581 And if they don't notice, they're not going to respond 233 00:11:26,581 --> 00:11:29,363 with a big change in the quantity demanded. 234 00:11:29,363 --> 00:11:31,256 On the other hand, if we have a product 235 00:11:31,256 --> 00:11:33,461 which is a large part of the budget, 236 00:11:33,461 --> 00:11:35,239 consumers will notice. 237 00:11:35,239 --> 00:11:38,440 Consumers notice when the price of automobiles goes up -- 238 00:11:38,440 --> 00:11:40,299 that's a big purchase. 239 00:11:40,299 --> 00:11:42,418 They're going to shop around a lot. 240 00:11:42,418 --> 00:11:44,707 They're going to try and get a big bargain 241 00:11:44,707 --> 00:11:46,680 when the purchase is a large fraction 242 00:11:46,680 --> 00:11:48,453 of their budget. 243 00:11:48,453 --> 00:11:51,021 On the other hand, when the price of toothpicks 244 00:11:51,021 --> 00:11:53,980 goes up by a lot, that's not such a big deal. 245 00:11:53,980 --> 00:11:56,368 Consumers probably won't even notice 246 00:11:56,368 --> 00:11:58,978 whether toothpicks are $0.50 or a $1. 247 00:11:58,978 --> 00:12:01,703 That's a 50% increase in price, 248 00:12:01,703 --> 00:12:04,852 but you probably don't even notice that at the store. 249 00:12:05,223 --> 00:12:10,158 So small item at least in the short run more inelastic. 250 00:12:10,542 --> 00:12:12,798 Bigger items, the bigger part of the budget, 251 00:12:12,798 --> 00:12:18,410 ones the consumer notices, more elastic, more price sensitive. 252 00:12:18,991 --> 00:12:22,762 Let's summarize the determinants of the elasticity of demand. 253 00:12:22,968 --> 00:12:26,017 For less elastic goods, that means fewer substitutes. 254 00:12:26,250 --> 00:12:29,648 Short run, less time to adjust, necessities, 255 00:12:29,648 --> 00:12:31,493 small part of the budget. 256 00:12:31,771 --> 00:12:35,144 Each of these factors makes the demand curve less elastic. 257 00:12:36,685 --> 00:12:39,982 More elastic demand, that means more substitutes. 258 00:12:39,982 --> 00:12:45,321 Long run, more time to adjust. Luxuries, large part of the budget. 259 00:12:45,321 --> 00:12:48,564 These factors make a demand curve more elastic. 260 00:12:48,924 --> 00:12:52,743 If you have to, memorize these, but once you understand 261 00:12:52,743 --> 00:12:55,272 that elasticity means how responsive 262 00:12:55,272 --> 00:12:58,740 is the quantity demanded to a change in the price, 263 00:12:58,740 --> 00:13:03,350 then you'll be able to recreate or figure out these factors again. 264 00:13:04,485 --> 00:13:06,710 That's it for the elasticity of demand. 265 00:13:06,710 --> 00:13:09,953 Next time,we're going to take a closer look at technically 266 00:13:09,953 --> 00:13:11,599 how do we get a number? 267 00:13:11,599 --> 00:13:14,155 How do we calculate the elasticity of demand? 268 00:13:14,155 --> 00:13:17,707 Given some facts and figures on prices and quantity demanded, 269 00:13:17,707 --> 00:13:20,699 how do we calculate what the elasticity really is? 270 00:13:20,699 --> 00:13:22,470 What's the number? 271 00:13:23,630 --> 00:13:25,322 - [Narrator] If you want to test yourself, 272 00:13:25,322 --> 00:13:27,606 click Practice questions. 273 00:13:27,606 --> 00:13:30,971 Or if you're ready to move on, just click Next Video. 274 00:13:30,971 --> 00:13:35,981 ♪ [music] ♪