0:00:00.200,0:00:05.757 ♪ [music] ♪ 0:00:08.800,0:00:10.704 - [Alex] Today we're going to look[br]at the Coase Theorem 0:00:10.704,0:00:13.851 and market solutions[br]to externality problems. 0:00:14.400,0:00:17.698 Basically what Coase[br]pointed out in a remarkable paper 0:00:18.001,0:00:20.020 was that the problem[br]with external benefits 0:00:20.020,0:00:23.270 and external costs is not[br]that they're external, 0:00:23.840,0:00:26.909 but rather that property rights[br]in these cases 0:00:26.909,0:00:28.685 are vague and uncertain 0:00:28.685,0:00:31.261 and that transactions costs[br]are high. 0:00:31.861,0:00:33.540 Let's get started with an example. 0:00:38.100,0:00:40.873 The Nobel prize-winning[br]economist, James Meade, 0:00:40.873,0:00:43.098 argued that the market[br]would underprovide 0:00:43.098,0:00:45.550 honey and pollination services. 0:00:46.099,0:00:48.455 Bees, Meade argued, do two things. 0:00:48.455,0:00:50.238 First, they create honey. 0:00:50.470,0:00:52.326 That honey is bought[br]and sold in markets 0:00:52.326,0:00:54.016 and there's a price for the honey. 0:00:54.356,0:00:57.566 Second, however,[br]bees will also fly out 0:00:57.566,0:01:00.830 and they'll pollinate the crops[br]of nearby farmers. 0:01:01.170,0:01:03.067 That's a very useful service,[br]but Meade argued 0:01:03.067,0:01:07.156 that the farmers wouldn't[br]be paying for that service. 0:01:07.378,0:01:09.711 The pollination services,[br]Meade argued, 0:01:09.711,0:01:11.651 were an external benefit. 0:01:11.902,0:01:14.703 Because the beekeepers[br]were not being paid 0:01:14.703,0:01:17.045 for these useful[br]pollination services, 0:01:17.250,0:01:20.990 there would be too few bees,[br]and as a result, too little honey, 0:01:20.990,0:01:24.448 and also too little crops[br]and too little pollination services. 0:01:25.672,0:01:29.110 However, another economist,[br]Steven Cheung, 0:01:29.110,0:01:31.710 proved that the Nobel Prize winner[br]was wrong, 0:01:31.710,0:01:34.680 and he did so[br]by consulting the Yellow Pages. 0:01:35.122,0:01:38.342 Cheung discovered that pollination[br]in the United States, in fact, 0:01:38.342,0:01:41.308 is a $15 billion industry. 0:01:42.287,0:01:45.329 Beekeepers regularly truck[br]their bee colonies 0:01:45.329,0:01:47.670 around the country and they sell 0:01:47.670,0:01:50.323 their pollination services[br]to farmers. 0:01:50.789,0:01:54.196 Because the farmers[br]are paying the beekeepers 0:01:54.196,0:01:56.060 for the services of the bees, 0:01:56.060,0:01:58.109 the benefits in fact[br]are not external, 0:01:58.109,0:02:02.172 they're not on bystanders --[br]and the market works. 0:02:02.904,0:02:05.026 So why did Meade get it wrong? 0:02:05.445,0:02:08.680 What about the bees,[br]and what about the farmers, 0:02:08.680,0:02:11.399 made it possible[br]for this externality problem 0:02:11.399,0:02:13.149 to be solved by markets 0:02:13.149,0:02:16.012 when many other[br]externality problems are not? 0:02:17.250,0:02:18.840 The market for pollination works 0:02:18.840,0:02:23.240 despite the fact that bees seem[br]to create this external benefit 0:02:23.619,0:02:26.105 because transactions costs are low. 0:02:26.382,0:02:29.250 That is, all of the costs[br]necessary for buyers and sellers 0:02:29.250,0:02:31.296 to reach an agreement are low. 0:02:31.652,0:02:35.961 In particular,[br]bees simply don't fly very far. 0:02:36.662,0:02:40.091 So an agreement between[br]one beekeeper and one farmer 0:02:40.542,0:02:43.163 can internalize all the externality. 0:02:43.613,0:02:45.608 That is, if the beekeeper[br]puts his bees 0:02:45.608,0:02:47.158 in the middle of the farm, 0:02:47.432,0:02:51.447 basically the only crops[br]which are going to be pollinated 0:02:51.447,0:02:54.192 are the crops[br]of that single farmer. 0:02:55.038,0:02:56.979 So once an agreement is made 0:02:56.979,0:02:59.657 between that beekeeper[br]and that farmer, 0:02:59.657,0:03:02.962 all of the externalities[br]have been internalized. 0:03:02.962,0:03:04.882 There are no bystanders 0:03:05.458,0:03:08.343 once the beekeeper and the farmer[br]make an agreement. 0:03:09.092,0:03:12.510 Moreover, the property rights here[br]are very clear. 0:03:12.925,0:03:15.875 The beekeeper has[br]the rights to the honey. 0:03:16.380,0:03:19.794 The farmer owns the crops[br]that the bees pollinate. 0:03:19.794,0:03:22.750 There isn't going to be a lot[br]of bargaining and disagreement 0:03:22.750,0:03:24.548 about who owns what. 0:03:24.548,0:03:26.681 The property rights are clear. 0:03:26.987,0:03:29.340 In other cases of externalities, 0:03:29.340,0:03:31.980 some of the ones[br]we've looked at previously, 0:03:31.980,0:03:34.310 neither of these things are true. 0:03:34.860,0:03:38.890 Transactions costs are high[br]and property rights are unclear. 0:03:40.199,0:03:42.318 Let's compare with pollution[br]and flu shots. 0:03:42.525,0:03:45.440 In both cases here,[br]the transactions costs are high 0:03:45.440,0:03:48.191 and property rights[br]are unclear and uncertain. 0:03:48.410,0:03:51.549 Consider pollution:[br]there's an external cost -- 0:03:51.720,0:03:54.703 the factory is putting[br]lots of pollution up into the sky, 0:03:55.020,0:03:56.099 but on who? 0:03:56.380,0:03:57.990 It's not necessarily on the people 0:03:57.990,0:04:00.330 who live right next door[br]to the factory. 0:04:00.739,0:04:03.227 The pollution[br]could be causing acid rain, 0:04:03.227,0:04:05.651 which is ruining lakes[br]hundreds of miles away, 0:04:05.651,0:04:07.542 or it could be causing[br]global warming 0:04:07.542,0:04:09.269 which is increasing sea levels 0:04:09.269,0:04:12.475 and ruining people's lives[br]thousands of miles away. 0:04:12.738,0:04:15.232 And exactly what are the costs?[br]How much? 0:04:15.232,0:04:18.152 How can we measure these costs?[br]It's not obvious. 0:04:19.377,0:04:22.095 Moreover, who has the rights here? 0:04:22.530,0:04:24.997 Should the factory[br]have to pay to pollute? 0:04:24.997,0:04:26.731 Should it have to pay the people 0:04:26.731,0:04:29.558 to whom it imposes[br]an external cost? 0:04:29.558,0:04:34.658 Or, should the bystanders have[br]to pay the factory not to pollute? 0:04:34.658,0:04:37.117 Does the factory[br]have the right not to pollute, 0:04:37.117,0:04:40.287 and do the bystanders[br]have to pay the factory to stop? 0:04:41.281,0:04:44.041 If you think that's obvious,[br]let's consider a flu shot. 0:04:44.701,0:04:46.658 There are external benefits. 0:04:46.658,0:04:48.245 If I get a flu shot, for example, 0:04:48.245,0:04:51.457 I'm less likely to sneeze[br]on people on the subway 0:04:51.457,0:04:52.929 and give them the flu. 0:04:53.047,0:04:54.479 But that could be hundreds, 0:04:55.296,0:04:56.834 dozens of people,[br]hundreds of people. 0:04:56.834,0:05:00.597 I don't know exactly which people[br]get the external benefit. 0:05:00.870,0:05:02.888 And how much[br]is this external benefit? 0:05:02.888,0:05:04.903 It's hard to measure, once again. 0:05:06.027,0:05:10.142 Moreover, should people[br]have to pay me to get a flu shot 0:05:10.622,0:05:14.986 or should I have to pay others[br]if I don't get a shot? 0:05:16.061,0:05:17.880 Now, by the way, let's compare[br]these two things -- 0:05:17.880,0:05:19.657 the pollution and the flu shot. 0:05:19.657,0:05:21.576 If you thought it was obvious 0:05:21.576,0:05:24.425 that the factory should have[br]to pay to pollute 0:05:24.939,0:05:28.275 and not that the bystanders[br]should have to pay the factory, 0:05:28.275,0:05:30.223 well, consider the flu shot. 0:05:30.902,0:05:33.690 Isn't sneezing,[br]if you don't get a flu shot, 0:05:33.690,0:05:36.840 isn't sneezing,[br]isn't that like pollution? 0:05:37.120,0:05:38.687 Isn't that polluting? 0:05:38.687,0:05:41.418 Shouldn't the polluter,[br]the sneezer have to pay? 0:05:41.886,0:05:44.280 So in that case[br]you might want to argue 0:05:44.682,0:05:48.270 that if you don't get a flu shot,[br]you should have to pay others. 0:05:48.602,0:05:50.973 You're polluting on them, right? 0:05:51.235,0:05:53.533 So the rights here[br]are not as obvious 0:05:53.533,0:05:55.491 as we might think at first glance. 0:05:55.993,0:05:59.920 Moreover, the main point is[br]that the transactions costs 0:05:59.920,0:06:01.566 of coming to an agreement 0:06:01.566,0:06:03.029 between these hundreds[br]or thousands 0:06:03.029,0:06:04.898 or perhaps millions of people, 0:06:05.130,0:06:07.154 figuring out[br]what the external costs are, 0:06:07.154,0:06:10.370 making that bargain,[br]that's going to be very costly. 0:06:11.133,0:06:14.787 And, we can't even agree[br]on who has the rights here, 0:06:15.048,0:06:17.369 or it's very difficult[br]to come to an agreement. 0:06:17.563,0:06:19.212 Should the factory have to pay? 0:06:19.212,0:06:21.592 Should the factory[br]be the one to be paid? 0:06:21.841,0:06:24.765 Should the person[br]getting the flu shot be paid, 0:06:24.765,0:06:28.590 or should the person not getting[br]the flu shot have to pay? 0:06:29.103,0:06:32.854 The rights here are uncertain,[br]and unclear, and again, 0:06:32.854,0:06:36.221 that's also going to make[br]coming to a market agreement 0:06:36.221,0:06:38.029 difficult to do, 0:06:38.029,0:06:40.550 and therefore the market[br]isn't going to solve these types 0:06:40.550,0:06:43.192 of externality problems[br]very easily. 0:06:43.890,0:06:47.404 So the conclusion here is[br]that the market can be efficient 0:06:47.404,0:06:49.574 even when there are externalities -- 0:06:49.838,0:06:52.000 when transactions costs are low 0:06:52.000,0:06:54.416 and when property rights[br]are clearly defined. 0:06:54.687,0:06:56.837 And in fact[br]that's the Coase Theorem. 0:06:57.246,0:06:58.880 If transactions costs are low 0:06:58.880,0:07:01.368 and property rights[br]are clearly defined, 0:07:01.368,0:07:03.408 private bargains will ensure 0:07:03.408,0:07:05.865 that the market equilibrium[br]is efficient 0:07:05.865,0:07:08.418 even if there are externalities. 0:07:08.990,0:07:11.154 The conditions[br]for the Coase Theorem to be met -- 0:07:11.154,0:07:13.886 low transactions costs[br]and clear property rights -- 0:07:14.156,0:07:16.663 are in practice often not met. 0:07:17.119,0:07:20.192 Even so, however,[br]the theorem does suggest 0:07:20.192,0:07:22.927 an alternative approach[br]to externalities. 0:07:23.193,0:07:26.040 We've already looked at[br]Pigouvian taxes and subsidies, 0:07:26.040,0:07:27.579 and command and control. 0:07:27.906,0:07:30.406 The Coase Theorem[br]suggests another solution, 0:07:30.840,0:07:33.920 namely the creation of new markets. 0:07:34.402,0:07:38.013 If the government[br]can define property rights 0:07:38.499,0:07:40.575 and reduce transactions costs, 0:07:41.107,0:07:45.170 then markets can be used[br]to control externality problems. 0:07:45.605,0:07:48.779 So the Coase Theorem plus[br]a little bit of command and control 0:07:48.779,0:07:52.680 in terms of defining property rights[br]and reducing transactions costs, 0:07:52.680,0:07:56.701 can create a new form of solution[br]to externality problems. 0:07:56.966,0:08:00.840 And in fact tradable permits is[br]what we're going to be looking at 0:08:00.840,0:08:02.195 in the next talk. 0:08:03.619,0:08:05.150 - [Narrator] If you want[br]to test yourself, 0:08:05.150,0:08:06.670 click "Practice Questions." 0:08:07.570,0:08:10.897 Or, if you're ready to move on,[br]just click "Next Video." 0:08:11.037,0:08:14.890 ♪ [music] ♪