Return to Video

When you're making a deal, what's going on in your brain?

  • 0:01 - 0:03
    I'm going to talk about
    the strategizing brain.
  • 0:03 - 0:06
    We're going to use an unusual
    combination of tools
  • 0:06 - 0:07
    from game theory and neuroscience
  • 0:07 - 0:11
    to understand how people interact socially
    when value is on the line.
  • 0:11 - 0:14
    So game theory is a branch of,
    originally, applied mathematics,
  • 0:14 - 0:17
    used mostly in economics and political
    science, a little bit in biology,
  • 0:18 - 0:20
    that gives us a mathematical
    taxonomy of social life,
  • 0:20 - 0:23
    and it predicts what people
    are likely to do
  • 0:23 - 0:24
    and believe others will do
  • 0:24 - 0:27
    in cases where everyone's actions
    affect everyone else.
  • 0:27 - 0:31
    That's a lot of things: competition,
    cooperation, bargaining,
  • 0:31 - 0:33
    games like hide-and-seek and poker.
  • 0:34 - 0:36
    Here's a simple game to get us started.
  • 0:36 - 0:38
    Everyone chooses a number
    from zero to 100.
  • 0:38 - 0:41
    We're going to compute
    the average of those numbers,
  • 0:41 - 0:45
    and whoever's closest to two-thirds
    of the average wins a fixed prize.
  • 0:45 - 0:48
    So you want to be a little bit
    below the average number
  • 0:48 - 0:49
    but not too far below,
  • 0:49 - 0:53
    and everyone else wants to be a little bit
    below the average number as well.
  • 0:53 - 0:54
    Think about what you might pick.
  • 0:54 - 0:55
    As you're thinking,
  • 0:55 - 0:58
    this is a toy model of something like
    selling in the stock market
  • 0:58 - 1:00
    during a rising market:
  • 1:00 - 1:03
    You don't want to sell too early,
    because you miss out on profits,
  • 1:03 - 1:06
    but you don't want to wait too late,
    to when everyone else sells,
  • 1:06 - 1:07
    triggering a crash.
  • 1:07 - 1:11
    You want to be a little bit ahead
    of the competition, but not too far ahead.
  • 1:11 - 1:14
    OK, here's two theories
    about how people might think about this,
  • 1:14 - 1:15
    then we'll see some data.
  • 1:15 - 1:17
    Some of these will sound familiar
  • 1:17 - 1:19
    because you probably
    are thinking that way.
  • 1:19 - 1:21
    I'm using my brain theory to see.
  • 1:21 - 1:24
    A lot of people say, "I really don't know
    what people are going to pick,
  • 1:24 - 1:28
    so I think the average will be 50" --
    they're not being strategic at all --
  • 1:28 - 1:30
    and "I'll pick two-thirds
    of 50, that's 33."
  • 1:30 - 1:31
    That's a start.
  • 1:31 - 1:33
    Other people, who are a little
    more sophisticated,
  • 1:33 - 1:35
    using more working memory,
  • 1:35 - 1:36
    say, "I think people will pick 33,
  • 1:36 - 1:39
    because they're going
    to pick a response to 50,
  • 1:39 - 1:41
    and so I'll pick 22,
    which is two-thirds of 33."
  • 1:41 - 1:43
    They're doing one extra step
    of thinking, two steps.
  • 1:44 - 1:45
    That's better.
  • 1:45 - 1:48
    Of course, in principle,
    you could do three, four or more,
  • 1:48 - 1:50
    but it starts to get very difficult.
  • 1:50 - 1:52
    Just like in language and other domains,
  • 1:52 - 1:55
    we know that it's hard for people
    to parse very complex sentences
  • 1:55 - 1:56
    with a recursive structure.
  • 1:56 - 1:58
    This is called the cognitive
    hierarchy theory,
  • 1:58 - 2:01
    something I've worked on
    and a few other people,
  • 2:01 - 2:02
    and it indicates a kind of hierarchy,
  • 2:02 - 2:06
    along with some assumptions about
    how many people stop at different steps
  • 2:06 - 2:08
    and how the steps of thinking are affected
  • 2:08 - 2:10
    by lots of interesting variables
    and variant people,
  • 2:10 - 2:12
    as we'll see in a minute.
  • 2:12 - 2:15
    A very different theory, a much
    more popular one and an older one,
  • 2:15 - 2:17
    due largely to John Nash
    of "A Beautiful Mind" fame,
  • 2:17 - 2:19
    is what's called "equilibrium analysis."
  • 2:19 - 2:22
    So if you've ever taken
    a game theory course at any level,
  • 2:22 - 2:24
    you'll have learned a bit about this.
  • 2:24 - 2:26
    An equilibrium is a mathematical state
  • 2:26 - 2:29
    in which everybody has figured out
    exactly what everyone else will do.
  • 2:29 - 2:31
    It is a very useful concept,
  • 2:31 - 2:33
    but behaviorally,
    it may not exactly explain
  • 2:33 - 2:36
    what people do the first time they play
    these types of economic games
  • 2:36 - 2:38
    or in situations in the outside world.
  • 2:38 - 2:41
    In this case, the equilibrium
    makes a very bold prediction,
  • 2:41 - 2:43
    which is: everyone wants
    to be below everyone else,
  • 2:43 - 2:45
    therefore, they'll play zero.
  • 2:46 - 2:47
    Let's see what happens.
  • 2:47 - 2:49
    This experiment's been done
    many, many times.
  • 2:49 - 2:51
    Some of the earliest ones
    were done in the '90s
  • 2:51 - 2:53
    by me and Rosemarie Nagel and others.
  • 2:53 - 2:56
    This is a beautiful data set
    of 9,000 people
  • 2:56 - 2:59
    who wrote in to three newspapers
    and magazines that had a contest.
  • 2:59 - 3:01
    The contest said, send in your numbers,
  • 3:01 - 3:04
    and whoever is close to two-thirds
    of the average will win a big prize.
  • 3:04 - 3:08
    As you can see, there's so much data
    here, you can see the spikes very visibly.
  • 3:08 - 3:11
    There's a spike at 33 --
    those are people doing one step.
  • 3:11 - 3:13
    There is another spike visible at 22.
  • 3:13 - 3:16
    Notice, by the way, most people
    pick numbers right around there;
  • 3:16 - 3:18
    they don't necessarily
    pick exactly 33 and 22.
  • 3:18 - 3:20
    There's something a bit noisy around it.
  • 3:20 - 3:22
    But you can see those spikes on that end.
  • 3:22 - 3:24
    There's another group of people
  • 3:24 - 3:26
    who seem to have a firm grip
    on equilibrium analysis,
  • 3:26 - 3:28
    because they're picking zero or one.
  • 3:28 - 3:30
    But they lose, right?
  • 3:30 - 3:33
    Because picking a number that low
    is actually a bad choice
  • 3:33 - 3:36
    if other people aren't doing
    equilibrium analysis as well.
  • 3:36 - 3:37
    So they're smart, but poor.
  • 3:38 - 3:40
    (Laughter)
  • 3:40 - 3:42
    Where are these things
    happening in the brain?
  • 3:42 - 3:46
    One study by Coricelli and Nagel
    gives a really sharp, interesting answer.
  • 3:46 - 3:50
    They had people play this game
    while they were being scanned in an fMRI,
  • 3:50 - 3:51
    and two conditions:
  • 3:51 - 3:52
    in some trials, they're told,
  • 3:52 - 3:55
    "You're playing another person
    who's playing right now.
  • 3:55 - 3:58
    We'll match up your behavior
    at the end and pay you if you win."
  • 3:58 - 4:01
    In other trials, they're told,
    "You're playing a computer,
  • 4:01 - 4:02
    they're just choosing randomly."
  • 4:02 - 4:04
    So what you see here
    is a subtraction of areas
  • 4:04 - 4:07
    in which there's more brain activity
    when you're playing people
  • 4:07 - 4:09
    compared to playing the computer.
  • 4:09 - 4:11
    And you see activity
    in some regions we've seen today,
  • 4:12 - 4:14
    medial prefrontal cortex,
    dorsomedial, up here,
  • 4:14 - 4:16
    ventromedial prefrontal cortex,
    anterior cingulate,
  • 4:16 - 4:19
    an area that's involved
    in lots of types of conflict resolution,
  • 4:19 - 4:21
    like if you're playing "Simon Says,"
  • 4:21 - 4:24
    and also the right and left
    temporoparietal junction.
  • 4:24 - 4:27
    And these are all areas
    which are fairly reliably known to be
  • 4:27 - 4:29
    part of what's called
    a "theory of mind" circuit
  • 4:29 - 4:31
    or "mentalizing circuit."
  • 4:31 - 4:34
    That is, it's a circuit that's used
    to imagine what other people might do.
  • 4:34 - 4:38
    These were some of the first studies
    to see this tied in to game theory.
  • 4:39 - 4:41
    What happens with these
    one- and two-step types?
  • 4:41 - 4:43
    So, we classify people
    by what they picked,
  • 4:43 - 4:47
    and then we look at the difference
    between playing humans versus computers,
  • 4:47 - 4:49
    which brain areas
    are differentially active.
  • 4:49 - 4:51
    On the top, you see the one-step players.
  • 4:51 - 4:52
    There's almost no difference.
  • 4:52 - 4:55
    The reason is, they're treating
    other people like a computer,
  • 4:55 - 4:56
    and the brain is too.
  • 4:56 - 4:59
    The bottom players, you see
    all the activity in dorsomedial PFC.
  • 4:59 - 5:02
    So we know the two-step players
    are doing something differently.
  • 5:03 - 5:05
    Now, what can we do with this information?
  • 5:05 - 5:07
    You might be able to look
    at brain activity and say,
  • 5:07 - 5:11
    "This person will be a good poker player,"
    or "This person's socially naive."
  • 5:11 - 5:14
    We might also be able to study things
    like development of adolescent brains
  • 5:14 - 5:17
    once we have an idea
    of where this circuitry exists.
  • 5:17 - 5:18
    OK. Get ready.
  • 5:18 - 5:20
    I'm saving you some brain activity,
  • 5:20 - 5:23
    because you don't need to use
    your hair detector cells.
  • 5:23 - 5:26
    You should use those cells
    to think carefully about this game.
  • 5:26 - 5:28
    This is a bargaining game.
  • 5:28 - 5:31
    Two players who are being
    scanned using EEG electrodes
  • 5:31 - 5:33
    are going to bargain
    over one to six dollars.
  • 5:33 - 5:36
    If they can do it in 10 seconds,
    they'll earn that money.
  • 5:36 - 5:39
    If 10 seconds go by and they haven't
    made a deal, they get nothing.
  • 5:39 - 5:41
    That's kind of a mistake together.
  • 5:41 - 5:44
    The twist is that one player, on the left,
  • 5:44 - 5:46
    is informed about how much
    on each trial there is.
  • 5:46 - 5:49
    They play lots of trials
    with different amounts each time.
  • 5:49 - 5:51
    In this case, they know
    there's four dollars.
  • 5:51 - 5:54
    The uninformed player doesn't know,
    but they know the informed player knows.
  • 5:54 - 5:57
    So the uninformed player's
    challenge is to say,
  • 5:57 - 5:58
    "Is this guy being fair,
  • 5:58 - 6:00
    or are they giving me a very low offer
  • 6:00 - 6:04
    in order to get me to think there's only
    one or two dollars available to split?"
  • 6:04 - 6:06
    in which case they might reject it
    and not come to a deal.
  • 6:06 - 6:09
    So there's some tension here
    between trying to get the most money
  • 6:09 - 6:12
    but trying to goad the other player
    into giving you more.
  • 6:12 - 6:15
    And the way they bargain
    is to point on a number line
  • 6:15 - 6:16
    that goes from zero to six dollars.
  • 6:16 - 6:19
    They're bargaining over how much
    the uninformed player gets,
  • 6:19 - 6:21
    and the informed player will get the rest.
  • 6:21 - 6:23
    So this is like
    a management-labor negotiation
  • 6:23 - 6:25
    in which the workers don't know
  • 6:25 - 6:28
    how much profits
    the privately held company has,
  • 6:28 - 6:31
    and they want to maybe
    hold out for more money,
  • 6:31 - 6:33
    but the company might want
    to create the impression
  • 6:33 - 6:36
    that there's very little to split:
    "I'm giving the most I can."
  • 6:36 - 6:40
    First, some behavior: a bunch
    of the subject pairs play face-to-face.
  • 6:40 - 6:42
    We have other data
    where they play across computers.
  • 6:42 - 6:45
    That's an interesting difference,
    as you might imagine.
  • 6:45 - 6:46
    But a bunch of the face-to-face pairs
  • 6:47 - 6:49
    agree to divide the money
    evenly every single time.
  • 6:49 - 6:52
    Boring. It's just not
    interesting neurally.
  • 6:52 - 6:55
    It's good for them --
    they make a lot of money.
  • 6:55 - 6:56
    But we're interested in:
  • 6:56 - 7:00
    Can we say something about when
    disagreements occur versus don't occur?
  • 7:00 - 7:03
    So this is the other group
    of subjects, who often disagree.
  • 7:03 - 7:06
    They bicker and disagree
    and end up with less money.
  • 7:06 - 7:09
    They might be eligible to be
    on "Real Housewives," the TV show.
  • 7:09 - 7:10
    (Laughter)
  • 7:10 - 7:12
    You see on the left,
  • 7:12 - 7:15
    when the amount to divide
    is one, two or three dollars,
  • 7:15 - 7:16
    they disagree about half the time;
  • 7:16 - 7:19
    when it's four, five, six,
    they agree quite often.
  • 7:19 - 7:21
    This turns out to be
    something that's predicted
  • 7:21 - 7:23
    by a very complicated type of game theory
  • 7:23 - 7:26
    you should come to graduate school
    at CalTech and learn about.
  • 7:26 - 7:28
    It's a little too complicated
    to explain right now,
  • 7:28 - 7:31
    but the theory tells you
    that this shape should occur.
  • 7:31 - 7:33
    Your intuition might tell you that, too.
  • 7:33 - 7:36
    Now I'm going to show you
    the results from the EEG recording.
  • 7:36 - 7:37
    Very complicated.
  • 7:37 - 7:40
    The right brain schematic
    is the uninformed person,
  • 7:40 - 7:41
    and the left is the informed.
  • 7:41 - 7:44
    Remember that we scanned
    both brains at the same time,
  • 7:44 - 7:46
    so we can ask about time-synced activity
  • 7:46 - 7:49
    in similar or different
    areas simultaneously,
  • 7:49 - 7:51
    just like if you wanted
    to study a conversation,
  • 7:51 - 7:54
    and you were scanning two people
    talking to each other.
  • 7:54 - 7:56
    You'd expect common
    activity in language regions
  • 7:56 - 7:58
    when they're listening and communicating.
  • 7:58 - 8:02
    So the arrows connect regions
    that are active at the same time.
  • 8:02 - 8:04
    The direction of the arrows
  • 8:04 - 8:06
    flows from the region
    that's active first in time,
  • 8:06 - 8:10
    and the arrowhead goes
    to the region that's active later.
  • 8:10 - 8:12
    So in this case, if you look carefully,
  • 8:12 - 8:14
    most of the arrows
    flow from right to left.
  • 8:14 - 8:18
    That is, it looks
    as if the uninformed brain activity
  • 8:18 - 8:19
    is happening first,
  • 8:19 - 8:23
    and then it's followed
    by activity in the informed brain.
  • 8:23 - 8:27
    And by the way, these are trials
    where their deals were made.
  • 8:27 - 8:28
    This is from the first two seconds.
  • 8:28 - 8:31
    We haven't finished analyzing this data,
    so we're still peeking in,
  • 8:32 - 8:35
    but the hope is that we can say something
    in the first couple of seconds
  • 8:35 - 8:37
    about whether they'll make a deal or not,
  • 8:37 - 8:40
    which could be very useful in thinking
    about avoiding litigation
  • 8:40 - 8:42
    and ugly divorces and things like that.
  • 8:42 - 8:46
    Those are all cases in which a lot
    of value is lost by delay and strikes.
  • 8:47 - 8:49
    Here's the case where
    the disagreements occur.
  • 8:49 - 8:51
    You can see it looks different
    than the one before.
  • 8:51 - 8:53
    There's a lot more arrows.
  • 8:53 - 8:55
    That means that the brains
    are synced up more closely
  • 8:55 - 8:57
    in terms of simultaneous activity,
  • 8:57 - 8:59
    and the arrows flow clearly
    from left to right.
  • 8:59 - 9:01
    That is, the informed brain
    seems to be deciding,
  • 9:01 - 9:04
    "We're probably not going
    to make a deal here."
  • 9:04 - 9:06
    And then later, there's activity
    in the uninformed brain.
  • 9:07 - 9:09
    Next, I'm going to introduce you
    to some relatives.
  • 9:09 - 9:11
    They're hairy, smelly, fast and strong.
  • 9:11 - 9:14
    You might be thinking back
    to your last Thanksgiving.
  • 9:14 - 9:15
    (Laughter)
  • 9:15 - 9:17
    Maybe, if you had a chimpanzee with you.
  • 9:17 - 9:21
    Charles Darwin and I and you broke
    off from the family tree from chimpanzees
  • 9:22 - 9:23
    about five million years ago.
  • 9:23 - 9:25
    They're still our closest genetic kin.
  • 9:25 - 9:26
    We share 98.8 percent of the genes.
  • 9:27 - 9:29
    We share more genes with them
    than zebras do with horses.
  • 9:29 - 9:31
    And we're also their closest cousin.
  • 9:31 - 9:34
    They have more genetic relation
    to us than to gorillas.
  • 9:34 - 9:37
    So, how humans and chimpanzees
    behave differently
  • 9:37 - 9:39
    might tell us a lot about brain evolution.
  • 9:39 - 9:42
    This is an amazing memory test
  • 9:42 - 9:44
    from [Kyoto], Japan,
    the Primate Research Institute,
  • 9:44 - 9:46
    where they've done a lot of this research.
  • 9:46 - 9:49
    This goes back a ways.
    They're interested in working memory.
  • 9:49 - 9:51
    The chimp will see, watch carefully,
  • 9:51 - 9:55
    they'll see 200 milliseconds' exposure --
    that's fast, eight movie frames --
  • 9:55 - 9:57
    of numbers one, two, three, four, five.
  • 9:57 - 9:59
    Then they disappear
    and are replaced by squares,
  • 9:59 - 10:01
    and they have to press the squares
  • 10:01 - 10:03
    that correspond to the numbers
    from low to high
  • 10:03 - 10:04
    to get an apple reward.
  • 10:04 - 10:06
    Let's see how they can do it.
  • 10:16 - 10:18
    This is a young chimp.
  • 10:18 - 10:21
    The young ones are better
    than the old ones, just like humans.
  • 10:21 - 10:22
    (Laughter)
  • 10:22 - 10:23
    And they're highly experienced,
  • 10:23 - 10:25
    they've done this thousands of times.
  • 10:25 - 10:28
    Obviously there's a big training
    effect, as you can imagine.
  • 10:28 - 10:29
    (Laughter)
  • 10:29 - 10:32
    You can see they're very
    blasé and effortless.
  • 10:32 - 10:35
    Not only can they do it very well,
    they do it in a sort of lazy way.
  • 10:35 - 10:36
    (Laughter)
  • 10:36 - 10:38
    Who thinks you could beat the chimps?
  • 10:38 - 10:39
    (Laughter)
  • 10:39 - 10:40
    Wrong. (Laughter)
  • 10:40 - 10:43
    We can try. We'll try. Maybe we'll try.
  • 10:43 - 10:47
    OK, so the next part of the study
    I'm going to go quickly through
  • 10:47 - 10:50
    is based on an idea of Tetsuro Matsuzawa.
  • 10:50 - 10:53
    He had a bold idea he called
    the "cognitive trade-off hypothesis."
  • 10:53 - 10:57
    We know chimps are faster and stronger;
    they're also obsessed with status.
  • 10:57 - 10:59
    His thought was, maybe
    they've preserved brain activities
  • 10:59 - 11:01
    and practice them in development
  • 11:01 - 11:05
    that are really, really important to them
    to negotiate status and to win,
  • 11:05 - 11:08
    which is something like strategic
    thinking during competition.
  • 11:08 - 11:09
    So we're going to check that out
  • 11:09 - 11:12
    by having the chimps actually play a game
  • 11:12 - 11:14
    by touching two touch screens.
  • 11:14 - 11:18
    The chimps are interacting
    with each other through the computers.
  • 11:18 - 11:19
    They'll press left or right.
  • 11:19 - 11:22
    One chimp is called a matcher;
    they win if they press left-left,
  • 11:22 - 11:26
    like a seeker finding someone
    in hide-and-seek, or right-right.
  • 11:26 - 11:27
    The mismatcher wants to mismatch;
  • 11:27 - 11:30
    they want to press
    the opposite screen of the chimp.
  • 11:30 - 11:32
    And the rewards are apple cube rewards.
  • 11:32 - 11:35
    So here's how game theorists
    look at these data.
  • 11:35 - 11:37
    This is a graph of the percentage of times
  • 11:37 - 11:39
    the matcher picked right on the x-axis
  • 11:39 - 11:41
    and the percentage of times
    they picked right
  • 11:41 - 11:43
    by the mismatcher on the y-axis.
  • 11:44 - 11:47
    So a point here is the behavior
    by a pair of players,
  • 11:47 - 11:49
    one trying to match,
    one trying to mismatch.
  • 11:49 - 11:52
    The NE square in the middle --
    actually, NE, CH and QRE --
  • 11:52 - 11:56
    those are three different theories
    of Nash equilibrium and others,
  • 11:56 - 11:57
    tells you what the theory predicts,
  • 11:57 - 11:59
    which is that they should match 50-50,
  • 11:59 - 12:02
    because if you play left
    too much, for example,
  • 12:02 - 12:05
    I can exploit that if I'm the mismatcher
    by then playing right.
  • 12:05 - 12:08
    And as you can see, the chimps --
    each chimp is one triangle --
  • 12:08 - 12:11
    are circled around,
    hovering around that prediction.
  • 12:11 - 12:13
    Now we move the payoffs.
  • 12:13 - 12:16
    We're going to make the left-left payoff
    for the matcher a little higher.
  • 12:16 - 12:18
    Now they get three apple cubes.
  • 12:18 - 12:21
    Game theoretically, that should
    make the mismatcher's behavior shift:
  • 12:21 - 12:25
    the mismatcher will think, "Oh, this guy's
    going to go for the big reward,
  • 12:25 - 12:27
    so I'll go to the right,
    make sure he doesn't get it."
  • 12:27 - 12:29
    And as you can see,
    their behavior moves up
  • 12:29 - 12:32
    in the direction of this change
    in the Nash equilibrium.
  • 12:32 - 12:34
    Finally, we changed
    the payoffs one more time.
  • 12:34 - 12:36
    Now it's four apple cubes,
  • 12:36 - 12:38
    and their behavior again moves
    towards the Nash equilibrium.
  • 12:39 - 12:41
    It's sprinkled around,
    but if you average the chimps out,
  • 12:41 - 12:43
    they're really close, within .01.
  • 12:43 - 12:45
    They're actually closer
    than any species we've observed.
  • 12:45 - 12:49
    What about humans? You think
    you're smarter than a chimpanzee?
  • 12:49 - 12:53
    Here's two human groups in green and blue.
  • 12:53 - 12:56
    They're closer to 50-50; they're not
    responding to payoffs as closely.
  • 12:56 - 12:58
    And also if you study
    their learning in the game,
  • 12:58 - 13:00
    they aren't as sensitive
    to previous rewards.
  • 13:00 - 13:04
    The chimps play better than the humans,
    in terms of adhering to game theory.
  • 13:04 - 13:07
    And these are two different groups
    of humans, from Japan and Africa;
  • 13:07 - 13:09
    they replicate quite nicely.
  • 13:09 - 13:11
    None of them are close
    to where the chimps are.
  • 13:12 - 13:13
    So, some things we learned:
  • 13:13 - 13:17
    people seem to do a limited amount of
    strategic thinking using theory of mind.
  • 13:17 - 13:19
    We have preliminary
    evidence from bargaining
  • 13:19 - 13:22
    that early warning signs in the brain
    might be used to predict
  • 13:22 - 13:24
    whether there'll be a bad
    disagreement that costs money,
  • 13:24 - 13:27
    and chimps are "better"
    competitors than humans,
  • 13:27 - 13:28
    as judged by game theory.
  • 13:28 - 13:29
    Thank you.
  • 13:29 - 13:32
    (Applause)
Title:
When you're making a deal, what's going on in your brain?
Speaker:
Colin Camerer
Description:

When two people are trying to make a deal -- whether they’re competing or cooperating -- what’s really going on inside their brains? Behavioral economist Colin Camerer shows research that reveals just how little we’re able to predict what others are thinking. And he presents an unexpected study that shows chimpanzees might just be better at it than we are. (Filmed at TEDxCalTech.)

more » « less
Video Language:
English
Team:
closed TED
Project:
TEDTalks
Duration:
13:49
  • Hello,

    The English transcript was updated on 5/3/20. In addition to other edits, please note the following change:

    09:42 from Nagoya, Japan, Primate Research Institute ---> from [Kyoto], Japan, the Primate Research Institute

    Thank you!

English subtitles

Revisions Compare revisions